THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL A Study in British Workshop Politics BY CARTER L. GOODRICH WITH A FOREWORD BY R. H. TAWNEY FELLOW OF BALLIOI. COI.LEOE, OXFORD; LATE MEMBEa OF THE COAL INDUSTRY COMMISSION m NEW YORK HARCOURT, BRACE AND HOWE 1920 COPYRIGHT, 1920, BY HARCOURT, BRACK AND HOWE, nSTC. THC QUINN AND BODEN COMPANY HAHWAY, N, J ACKNOWLEDGMENTS Fob the fun I have had in doing this job, my two heaviest obligations are to Amherst College — for sending me to England to study — and to Mr. Henry Clay — for directing my work here. The trip was made possible by the award of the Boswell Dwight Hitchcock Fellowship to which the Trustees of Amherst College voted a special addition. My personal debts to the college and to the men working with President Meikle- john there are too many and too great to mention here. It is Professor Walton H. Hamilton, how- ever, to whose teaching I owe my start in labor problems and to whose planning I owe this special opportunity. To Mr. Henry Clay, late of the Ministry of Labour and now Fellow of New College, Oxford, I am indebted both for suggesting a job that ** wanted doing" and for giving me almost day- to-day counsel and guidance in the doing of it. Without the many kindnesses of Mr. Clay and his friends, I could hardly have begun to find my way about in an investigation of the current British situation. Mr. G. D. H. Cole and his associates of the Labour Research Department were good enough iii iv ACKNOWLEDGMENTS to give me access to their useful collection of trade union journals, constitutions, rules, etc. and to help me in other ways. Mr. R. H. Tawney, Mr. Arthur Grleason and Mr. Eobert W. Bruere have very kindly read my manuscript and made valuable suggestions. Finally I feel warmly grateful to a large number of people in various parts of Great Britain — employers and workers, managers, foremen, trade union secretaries, tutorial movement students and tutors, government officials and ''rebel" shop stewards — for the readiness and courtesy with which they have taken time from their immediate and practical concerns with industry to answer the questions of an outsider and an American. C. L, G. LONDOK, December 1, 1919. CONTENTS PAOB Acknowledgments iii Foreword by K. H. Tawney vii Introduction: The Demand for Control , . 3 The Extent of Control : SECTION I— Control • . . 51 II— The Frontier of Control .... 56 III — Employment 63 IV — Unemployment 72 V— ''The Right to a Trade" . ... 92 VI— "TheRigJitto Sack" .... 104 VII— Promotion Ill VIII— The Choice of Foremen . . . .117 IX — The Organization of Foremen . . 126 X — The Standard of Foremanship . .135 XI — Special Managerial Functions . . 146 XII— Methods of Payment .... 161 XIII — Technique: Restriction and Restrictions 176 XIV — Technique : Consultation over Changes . 186 XV — Technique : Insistence on Improvements 202 XVI — Technique: Suggestions and Inventions 217 XVII— Trade Policy: Joint Action . . .223 XVIII— Trade Policy: Workers' Demands . . 241 XIX— The Extent of Control . . . .253 Note on Sources 267 Index 273 Digitized by tlie Internet Arcliive in 2007 witli funding from IVIicrosoft Corporation littp://www.archive.org/details/frontierofcontroOOgoodiala FOREWORD By R. H. Tawney It is a commonplace that during the past six years the discussion of industrial and social prob-' lems has shifted its center. Prior to the war students and reformers were principally occupied with questions of poverty. To-day their main in- terest appears to be the government of industry. An increasing number of trade unionists regard poverty as a symptom of a more deeply rooted malady which they would describe as industrial autocracy and demand ''control." Anxious to establish some modus vivendi which may promise industrial peace, employers consider the conces- sion of a workshop committee or an industrial council. The Government gives the movement its official blessing and has taken steps through the Ministry of Labor to propagate the proposals of Mr. Whitley's Committee. That ** control" should stand to different sections of opinion for quite different types of industrial structure was only to be expected. But the necessity of meeting some demand for which that is now the accepted name is generally admitted. The formulation of a ''Constitution for Industry" is conducted with something of the same energy as that which past vii viii FOREWORD generations have given to the discussion of a Con- stitution for the State. The change of angle is interesting. No doubt it is all to the good that the task of reorganizing industry should be recognized for what it is — a particular case of the general problem of consti- tutional government. But if it has been useful to show that recent industrial movements have ''self-government" as their genus, it is no less im- portant now to be clear as to their species. The formulation of programs of ''joint control," such as — to give only one example — that advanced by the Miners' Federation, the demand for "indus- trial democracy," the analogies drawn between representative institutions in industry and in poli- tics— these things have been invaluable in broadening horizons and in opening windows through which new ideas could pass. But the emphasis needed to compel attention to the sig- nificance of a point of view which till recently was unfamiliar has by now, it may be suggested, done its work. The new field for investigation and practice has been mapped out. What is needed to-day is to give precision to its content and to test general propositions in the light of particular facts. "Control" is the most ambiguous and least self-explanatory of formulae. The aspira- tions behind it may be genuine enough. But un- less it is to remain a mere aspiration, it must be FOREWORD ix related much more closely than has been done hitherto to the actual conditions of industrial or- ganization and to the realities of human psy- chology. We must know how much control is wanted, and control over what, and through whom it is to be exercised. We must decide whether the demand is the passing result of abnormal eco- nomic conditions, produced by the war and seized upon by theorists as a basis for premature gen- eralizations, or whether it represents a move- ment which is so fundamental and permanent that any future scheme of industrial relationships, un- less it is to be built upon sand, must take account of it. The first condition of answering these questions is an impartial survey of the actual facts as they exist to-day. Mr. Carter Goodrich's book supplies it. He is concerned not with theory, but with practice. His object is not to propound any doc- trine, to suggest any reforms or to formulate a judgment as to the merits or demerits of any fea- tures in the industrial system. It is simply to offer the materials without the possession of which these exercises, however exhilarating, are apt to be sterile. He has set himself the question : — "How much control over industry do the rank and file of those who work in it, and their organi- zations, in fact exercise?'* He answers it by an analysis of industrial relationships, of the rules X FOREWORD enforced by trade unions and employers ' associa- tions, of the varying conditions which together constitute ''the custom of the trade" in each par- ticular industry, and of the changes in all of these which took place during the war. Such a study of ''The Frontier of Control" is indispensable to the formation of any reasonable judgment upon the larger issues which the phrase suggests. Mr. G-oodrich is well qualified to pro- vide it. He has made a careful investigation of such aspects of British industrial organization as are relevant to his subject. Residence in Great Britain has familiarized him with the atmosphere in which its industrial politics are carried on. He has mixed with members of Whitley Councils and Boards of Control, Trade Boards and Royal Com- missions, trade unions and employers' associa- tions. He knows what men of business like Mr. Foster and Mr. Malcolm Sparkes hope for the building industries and the views on mining of leading members of the Miners' Federation. To the economic perplexities and agitations of a foreign country he brings the wide background of a student of economics and a dash of charming skepticism which to one heated by the somewhat feverish temperature of British industry during the last two years, is as refreshing as the ice at the close of an American dinner. Mr. Goodrich has shown admirable self- FOREWORD xi restraint in allowing the facts to speak for them- selves, and in resisting the temptation to enlarge upon their moral. With regard to certain broad questions, however, his book encourages the reader to attempt the generalizations which the author withholds. It suggests, in the first place, that the sharp division ordinarily drawn between the sphere of "management" and that of ** labor'* is an abstraction which does less than justice to the complexity of the facts. If it is broadly true that in modern industry the function of the former is direction and of the latter the execution of orders transmitted to it, the line between them, nevertheless, fluctuates widely from industry to in- dustry. It varies, for one thing, quite irrespective of any deliberate effort on the part of the workers to move it, with the nature of the work which is being carried on. There are certain occupations in which an absolute separation between the plan- ning and the performance of work is, for technical reasons, impracticable. A group of miners who are cutting and filling coal are "working" hard enough. But very little coal will be cut, and the risks of their trade wiU. be enormously increased, unless they display some of the qualities of scien- tific knowledge, prevision and initiative which are usually associated with the word "management." What is true of miners is true, in diiferent de- grees, of men oa a building job or in the trans- xil FOREWORD port trades. They must exercise considerable discretion in their work because, unless they do, the work does not get done, and no amount of supervision can compensate for the absence of it. It is not, it may be suggestedj a mere chance that workers in these industries should have taken the initiative in the movement for ''control." They demand more of it, because the very nature of their work compels them to exercise something of it already. In industries such as these the character of the work pushes the frontier of the workmen's con- trol further into the employer's territory than is the case in — say — a cotton mill or a locomotive shop. But the degree to which workers exercise in some industries functions and powers reserved in others for the management does not depend merely upon economic conditions. It is also, of course, the result of conscious effort, which is not the less significant because till recently it took the form of specific claims to be consulted upon par- ticular matters incidental to the wage contract and was not related to any general social philosophy. The organization of sufficient power to assert those claims effectively is the history of trade unionism. Of its result in establishing or failing to establish them, Mr. Goodrich's book is the best account known to me. The reader can judge from it how much "control" had in practice been se- FOREWORD xiii cured by workmen up to 1919. If he compares tlie position with that which obtained fifty years ago he will see that long before the movement for *' self-government in industry" had become ex- plicit, the line between ''management" and ' * labor" had been, in fact, redrawn. On one point, apprenticeship and the entry to a trade, the ef- fective power of the workers appears for obvious reasons to have diminished. On all the rest it has enormously increased. As Mr. Groodrich's survey shows, the intensive development of trade union- ism has been even more remarkable than its ex- tensive growth in membership. On the whole group of questions, in particular, suggested by the word ''discipline," it is every year more and more succeeding in the establishment of the same claims as it made effective thirty years ago with regard to wages and hours. In the light of the facts presented by Mr. Good- rich it is a question whether the conventional description of industrial organization given in most economic text-books does not require a some- what radical revision. The picture of "the em- ployer" achieving economic progress by "substi- tuting" one "factor of production" for another may have been adequate to the early days of the factory system. What the present study brings out is the vital importance at every point of a condition which is apt to be lightly touched upon xiv FOREWORD or omitted altogether, tlie condition of corporate consent on the part of the workers. How vital that condition is is one of the discoveries of the past five years. It was emphasized first by the events of the war, which revealed how little reality there was in the common as- sumption that the settlement of the larger ques- tions of industrial organization was a matter for the employer and the employer alone. It became necessary to reorganize industry for the purpose of increasing production or of economizing mate- rials. The condition of carrying out the reorgani- zation effectively was the consent of all engaged in the industry. Consent could be obtained only by a formal recognition of the fact that the rep- resentative of the workers had a right to be con- sulted with regard to questions of policy and management, because they possessed de facto the power to frustrate the required changes or to make them effective. Hence, as Mr. Goodrich points out, the creation of representative organs, such as the Textile Control Boards, through which the views of the workers on these matters could be expressed. When, as in the textile trades, that representative machinery worked effectively, the emergency was met with compara- tively little difficulty. When, as in the engineer- ing trades, the policy pursued was to force drastic innovations upon workers who were not consulted FOREWORD XV with regard to them, the result was endless fric- tion. The moral suggested by the situation since the armistice in the building and coal-mining in- dustries— to mention no others — and emphasized by Mr. Foster's Committee, by Mr. Justice Sankey, and by the report on dock labor of Lord Shaw's Court of Inquiry, is the same. It is that, as matters now stand, the first condition of economic progress is such a change in the posi- tion of the workers as will throw on to the side of increased efficiency the public opinion which is at present skeptical both of the objects for which it is urged and of the methods by which it is sought to attain it. The truth is that, with the pushing forward of the ''frontier" through the process described by Mr. Goodrich, the conditions of industrial effi- ciency have changed. In no very remote past disci- pline could be imposed upon workers from above, under pain of dismissal, which meant in the last resort, however hateful it may be to confess it, by an appeal to hunger and fear. "Members of this Court," states Lord Shaw's report, ''can re- call a period when men, gathered at the dock gates, fought fiercely for a tally which, when obtained, might only enable them to obtain one hour's work, and so limit their earnings for the day to 4d." Workmen were conscious of individual grievances, but they had not formulated an interpretation of xvi FOREWORD their position in general terms, and the willing- ness of the personnel of industry to co-operate in production without raising fundamental questions as to its constitution and government could be taken for granted. To-day that assumption is possible only to the very short-sighted. As the present study shows, the effect of the piecemeal advances made by trade unionism has been to effect, in the aggregate, a radical redistribution of authority between the parties engaged in in- dustry, which results, in extreme cases, in some- thing like a balance of power. To discuss how that situation is to be resolved, whether by a frontal attack on trade unionism, such as appears to be favored by the more naive and irresponsi- ble section of opinion in the United States, or by giving it a vested interest in the con- tinuance of profit-making through schemes of profit-sharing and representation on directorates, or by a partnership between a trade unionism undertaking responsibility for the maintenance of professional standards and the consumer for whom industry is carried on, does not fall within the scope of Mr. Goodrich's book. But a reasonable consideration of these large and burning issues will be materially assisted by the clearness and impartiality with which he has set forth the pre- cise facts of the existing situation. R. H. Tawney. THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL INTRODUCTION THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL ''In the past workmen have thought that if they could secure higher wages and better conditions they would be content. Employers have thought that if they granted these things the workers ought to be contented. Wages and conditions have been improved; but the discontent and the unrest have not disappeared. ' ' So far the quota- tion might be from almost any American business man. But the place was the King's Robing Room of the British House of Lords, and the speaker was a veteran trade union leader, Mr. William Straker, presenting the case of the Miners' Federation before the Coal Commission which was sitting in judgment on Great Britain's key industry. Mr. Straker went on: — **Many good people have come to the conclusion that working people are so un- reasonable that it is useless trying to satisfy them. The fact is that the unrest is deeper than pounds, shillings and pence, necessary as they are. The root of the matter is the straining of the spirit of man to be free." In the name of this ** deeper" unrest, the Miners ' Federation was demanding a bold scheme 8 4 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL of workers' control. And the "deeper" unrest itself — or at least the unrest which is concerned more with discipline and management than with wages — is often spoken of as the demand for con- trol. The main business of this book is to discuss the facts of the present extent of workers ' control in British industry; the purpose of the introduc- tion is to indicate the significant setting of these facts in the human terms of the demand for con- trol. Control is important only because people want it. But how many workers do want control, and how much control do they want? No answer can pretend to be definite. Control is a slogan in several vigorous propagandist programs. Con- trol has more than once been a definite issue both in the active conflicts and the formulated policies of the labor movement. But even for this con- scions and organized demand, no accurate count of heads can be made. And for the much more significant estimate of the underlying demand for control — the desires of individual workers for the simpler things that are grouped as control, and the restlessnesses for which the word control is an attempted rationalization — it is possible only to offer a few clues for further study. Control is the central idea of various propa- gandist isms. The Syndicalist cry of 1911 — "The Mines for the Miners" — has died out, but THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 5 the idea of workers' control remains. ** Complete control of industry by the working-class organiza- tions," is the slogan of the Marxian Industrial Unionists/ Control of industry by guilds of pro- ducers co-operating with a democratized state representing the people as consumers, is the subtler syndicalism ^ of the Guild Socialists. And the cries of '^complete control" and ''encroaching control" of these groups of theorists are echoed more and more faintly through various grades of opinion to the "share in control" and ''voice in control" ^ offered in the Whitley Councils. The thoroughgoing disciples of either of the two com- plete gospels of control — Marxian Industrial Unionism and Guild Socialism — are a tiny minority. The Socialist Labor Party, the chief organization of the former, has about two thousand members, but this number included the ablest of the leaders of the shop stewards ' move- ment, and the movement served as a channel for the doctrine. The Centfal Labor College, which "promises to be candid but not impartial" and preaches an uncompromising revolutionary orthodoxy, reaches through its correspondence and other courses perhaps ten thousand students a year — chiefly among the members of the National * G. D. H. Cole, An Introduction to Trade Unionism, pp. 97, 98. * Cf. the footnote on p. 37 of Cole's Self-Oovernment in Industry. * The corresponding Americanisms are " management-sharing " and " voice in management." 6 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL Union of Railwaymen and the South Wales Miners' Federation. The Guild Socialists, too, are insignificant in enrolled members. The Na- tional Guilds League, their propagandist body, has less than a thousand members. This figure is, however, little indication of the actual number who accept more or less fully the guild idea and little indication of the actual influence of this small group — composed as it is largely of able and pro- lific writers and of the younger trade union officials. The working-class circulation of Mr. Cole's books, his personal influence as adviser to the labor movement, and the obvious guildsman's hand in documents such as the Miners' Bill for Nationalization* and the Foster Report to the Building Trades Parliament "—are suggestions of this. One shrewd observer declared that: — "The Guild Socialist propaganda has gone as far in the trade union movement in two years as the State Socialist propaganda had gone in twenty years." In addition to these elaborate and definite theories of control there is a large body of opin- ion that is agreed on some extension of workers* control as the next step in trade unionism. No trade union leader would admit that he wanted less control than the minimum offered in the Whitley Councils scheme — which is itself some in- ication of the spread of the control doctrine. * See below, p. 12. • See below, p. 86. THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 7 There is no one break in the long series from Syndicalism to Whitleyism, and the widespread acceptance of the latter in middle-class thinking is a hint of the driving force of the more drastic doctrines. Next possibly to ''nationalization," ** control" is the most talked-of word among trade union theorists. The control issue, moreover, has passed from labor theory into labor activity and declared pol- icy. Its most spectacular expression was in that revolt against or within trade unionism known as the Shop Stewards' Movement." This, it is true, was many things besides an expression of the de- mand for control. It began largely as a protest against the special helplessness of the trade imion leaders before the special war-time problems. The cost of living was rising sharply, dilution was threatening the wage standard of the skilled engi- neers,'' the number of war-time restrictions was multiplying. Meanwhile the trade union leaders were bound not to lead strikes — first by the "in- dustrial truce" agreed upon at the beginning of the war, later by the anti-strike provisions of the Munitions Act. The unrest broke out in spontane- ous and unauthorized strikes. The movement found leaders in the shop stewards or trade union representatives from within the various shops' • G. D. H. Cole, Introduction to Trade Unionitm, pp. 53-58. * See below, pp. 100 and 189. 8 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL men whose position before the war had meant little more than collecting dues for the union.* The issues were concrete and immediate. The first of these strikes was the ''Tuppenny Strike" for a long-delayed wage increase on the Clyde in Jan- uary, 1915. The strike committee of stewards elected from the various works organized per- manently as the Clyde Workers' Committee and this simple type of structure was copied by other districts. The movement at Sheffield broke out when a certain skilled engineer was drafted into the army. And so through the other engineering centers. The movement was first and most simply the workers' attempt by whatever means came handy to get the inmaediate concessions which their official machinery was failing to win. It became in part, however, a revolt against official- ism in general. This in fact furnished the chief dogma of the movement — "the vesting of control of policy in the rank and file" — and its common name, the "Rank and File Movement." "Refer grievances to the rank and file," and "Get a move on in the shop before reporting to official sources, ' ' are rules from the Sheffield Shop Stewards ' Man- ual. The movement was largely a breaking away from the cumbrous structure of engineering trade unionism. "We organize for power," wrote the • Ministry of Labour, Works Committees, pp. 2-10, See Note on Sources. THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 9 chief spokesman of the movement,^ *'and yet we find the workers in the workshop divided not only amongst a score of branches but a score of unions." Shop vs. branch and mditstry vs. craft, were the two issues of organization. The trade union branch in engineering is based on the residence, not the working-place, of the mem- bers. Men who work side by side may be scattered among a number of branches. But grievances arise in particular shops. Therefore ''Direct Representation from the Workshops to the Committees" is the first of the ''Principles" on the member's card of the Sheffield Workers* Committee. In the second place, the industry is organized in a score or more of separate and often competing trade unions.^" Jealousy frequently runs high between craft and craft and higher be- tween skilled and unskilled. The shop stewards ' movement took in all grades of labor and was in effect an amalgamation from below. "Work always for the solidarity of all the workers," is the last rule from the Shop Stewards' Manual. The movement was, then, a double attempt to fit the structure of the labor movement to the struc- ture of the industrial unit. So much for the motives other than the demand • J. T. Murphy, The Workers' Committee. See Note on Sources. '• Eight of these unions, including the Amalgamated Society of Engineers, have just voted to unite. 10 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL for control. The movement won its chief support by appeals to simple and very practical war-time issues ; its chief effect may possibly be in the field of trade union structure. But its connections with the demand for workers' control are close and highly significant. Whatever the rank and file wanted, the conspicuous leaders were out for control. This is evident in all the propaganda of the movement. The first of the ** Objects" on the Shefiield member's card was **To obtain an ever- increasing Control of Workshop Conditions." It is evident in such by-products of the movement as the Clyde Dilution Scheme " and the Gallecher- Paton memorandum on collective contract.^^ But it is clearest of all in the actual seizures of power by the shop stewards and in the way the leaders played on each particular grievance and played up each particular issue to swell the general de- mand for control. Several instances of shop steward tactics are given in Section X. The use of a particular blacksmith's objection to the boss's watching his fire to establish a general refusal to be watched at work is a minor but typical case." Moreover the very changes in structure themselves were often argued on control grounds: fit your organization to industry to make it fit to control industry. The shop stewards' movement was a '» See below, pp. 197-201. " See below, p. 173. " See below, p. 138. THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 11 genuine movement towards the control of industry. And as an object-lesson in control it has become a stimulus to further demands. The powers won by the shop stewards are being used up and down the country as a text for vigorous propaganda. The shop stewards' control was decidedly con- tagious control "; its actual extent may be easily underrated by an outsider. It was recorded in no formal agreements. It rested on the war shortage of labor and was abruptly checked in the period of unemployment that followed the end of the war. The full story has nowhere been put to- gether, and the evidence must be pieced out from th6 accounts of the shop stewards themselves and from employers' tales of "what they had to put up with during the war," but it is clear that the movement was enormously powerful throughout the great engineering centers and that it has spread to other industries, and it is clear that in certain works the shop stewards exercised the greatest degree of control ever held by British workers in modern industry. The shop stewards' movement was both an expression of the demand for control and an incitement to further demands. But the demand for control is by no means con- fined to ' ' rebel ' ' trade unionism. The demand that among the engineers broke through the union machinery has in other unions found its outlet in " See below, Section XIX. 12 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL oflScial programs. Its expressions in official trade union policy have been less picturesque than the unofficial outbreak, but they are no less signifi- cant. Two of the greatest trade unions, the Miners ' Federation with its 800,000 members and the National Union of Railwaymen with its 450,- 000, have not only accepted the principle of con- trol but have put forward specific schemes of con- trol as serious parts of their programs. At the annual conference of the Miners on July 9, 1918, the following resolution was carried: — "That in the opinion of this conference the time has arrived in the history of the coal mining industry when it is clearly in the national interests to transfer the entire industry from private ownership and control to State ownership with joint control and administror tion hy the workmen and the State" (italics mine). * ' The workmen should have some directive power in the industry in which they are engaged," said Mr. Frank Hodges in urging the resolution. **I do not believe that nationalization will do any good for anybody, unless it is accompanied by an effec- tive form of working-class control." Another leader declared: — **We have the brains amongst the miners to work the mines." The sense of this resolution was embodied in a Mines Nationaliza- tion Bill" which was drafted early in 1919 and " See below, Note on Sources. THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 13 presented to the Coal Commission. Under this scheme the industry would be administered, under a Minister of Mines, by a National Council made up of ten Government nominees and ten men chosen by the Miners' Federation and by a series of subordinate District and Pit Councils on each of which one half of the members should be di- rectly elected by the workers affected. The system of control outlined in the majority report of the Coal Commission, known as the Sankey Scheme,^* differs from this in the important particular that on each of these boards the workers are given slightly less than half of the places. The repre- sentatives of the Miners nevertheless accepted the Sankey Report with minor reservations. After the Government rejected it, it was endorsed by an overwhelming majority at the Trades Union Con- gress at Glasgow and is now the subject of vigor- ous propaganda on the part of the entire trade union movement. The National Union of Railwaymen was first committed to a control policy by the following resolution passed by a National Conference of District Councils early in 1917: — "That this Conference, seeing that the Railways are being controlled by the State for the benefit of the nation during the war, is of opinion that they should not revert to private ownership afterwards. Further, " See below. Note on Sources. U THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL we believe that national welfare demands that they should be acquired by the State to be jointly controlled and managed by the State and representatives of the N.U.R." Mr. Bellamy in his President's address that year declared : — "Whether nationalization or [state] control be de- cided upon, it ought to be made unmistakably clear that neither system will be acceptable to railwaymen unless we are given a share in the management." A special conference in November, 1917, voted by a majority of 74 to 1 : — "That there should be equal representation, both na- tional and local, for this union upon the management of all railways in the United Kingdom." In March, 1918, the Executive at a special meet- ing adopted a control scheme similar to that of the Miners and providing for a National Board of Control, half of whose members should be elected by the House of Commons and half by the railway trade unions. The scheme is now under negotia- tion with the Prime Minister and the Minister of Transport. The Government's counter offer seems to be an improvement in the Conciliation Board machinery — to allow for the hearing of grievances over discipline — and a small minority of places for the union on the Railway Executive Committee. THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 15 The Miners and Railwaymen, then, have put con- trol schemes into their official programs and have pressed them in their actual bargaining. The other unions have no such detailed proposals as parts of their serious immediate policy, but it would be easy to fill a book with statements from trade union journals and from responsible trade union officials that the control of industry is their ** ultimate aim." The Postal and Telegraph Clerks,^' whose leaders are all National Guilds- men, are definitely committed to a control policy. The following bit from a correspondent's letter is a fair sample of the tone of their official publi- cation : — "I am out for a Postal Guild; so is Francis. He wouldn't be worth a dime ... if he wasn't." But it is unnecessary to go down the list of individual unions to discover commitments of the trade union movement to the idea of control. The issue came before the 1'rades Union Congress at Glasgow in September, 1919. Mr. Bromley of the Locomotive Engineers moved a resolution favoring workers' control of industry to end ex- ploitation. The motion was carried unanimously and with some enthusiasm. Control has become an official and avowed aim of the whole labor movement. " Now a part of the new Union of Post Office Workers. 16 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL How mucli this commitment really means is another matter, A resolution carried unanimously and without debate at a Congress whose real interest was in the hot jfight over ** Direct Action" is hardly evidence of immediate responsible policy. But together with the other commitments to control, it is a significant sign of the times. It is at least a sign of the phenomenally rapid growth of the demand for control. In 1907, the leaders of the railwaymen declared in all honesty that they had no intention of having anything to do with discipline. In 1919, the railway unions are nego- tiating on the basis of a demand for half control of the entire management. This is partly a matter of the increased power of the union; a union's strength may be roughly gauged by the issues on which it fights. But it is largely a matter of a change in the ideas of the trade union movement. The demand for ''control of industry" in so many words is a new thing or possibly the revival of a long-forgotten thing. Bits of what would now be called control have long been fought for and often w«n by the trade unions — of that this whole book is evidence. But the conscious demand is a new and significant phenomenon. The very vocabulary. of control is new. It had hardly been heard before Mr. Tom Mann '' stumped England " A leader in the great dock strike of 1889, mass orator to three continents, now General Secretary of the Amalgamated Society of Engineers, THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 17 in 1911. All the movements discussed have started since that time. Eight years of propa- ganda at the most and a new and revolutionary- idea officially accepted by the trade union move- ment. The resolution indicates one more thing — that there is within trade unionism practically no active opposition to the idea of control. There is no doubt at all of the truth of Mr. Cole's claim in the Introduction of Trade Unionism that the theorists of control are in line with the immediate tendencies of the ** younger active trade union- ists." But just here must be made the first serious discount of the force of the demand. Younger active trade unionists are by any count a mere handful. The percentage of members interested in general policy is small in any union. *'I sometimes feel," said Mr. Hodges, ''that there is a great mountain of indifference even in the Mining Movement." Younger active trade unions are perhaps also a minority. Few unions have both the power and the desire to push forward programs of control. Many must be written off almost completely in any calculation of the demand. The great cotton unions have hardly been touched by the control propaganda. The aristocratic monopolists of the old crafts discussed in Section XIX make no part of the new demand. The women's unions have 18 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL showed little effective demand for control — so far at least dilution by woman labor has been also a dilution of the demand for control. All this is not to minimize the demand. Control has been genuinely fought for in trade union activity. The idea of control has officially captured the trade union movement. But to say that the trade union movement is committed to control by a resolution passed unanimously at Glasgow is not to say that control is actively demanded by each of the five and a quarter million trade unionists represented at the Congress. Nor is it to say that every trade union represented will fight for control. Trade unionism is no such coherent and united force. Nor is control so simple and definite a thing. The word is a slogan and a convenient general term. But in actual reference to the facts of in- dustry it breaks up into a bewildering variety of rights and claims — as the rest of the book will show. Control is no ''simple central objective," no one clear-cut thing which people either know they want or know they don't want. The demand cannot be put glibly into a single phrase or a single resolution — too many diverse motives are blended and crossed in the strivings of many workers for the complicated set of things called control. The demand for control is not the unified ex- THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 19 pression of some single specific impulse. If it were, it might be easier to separate it from the other strands of motive in industrial life. But instead, the elements of the demand must be hunted for in the whole jungle of the reactions of workers to the industrial situation. It is a hunt for facts that can neither be classified sharply nor weighed accurately. * ' It is essential, ' ' says the re- port of the Garton Foundation," '*to disentangle as far as possible the economic and non-economic factors. ' ' That would be hard enough, but would lead only to the edge of the problem of distinguish- ing among the non-economic factors. It is a study to which there is no end, but even the most tenta- tive beginning may fill in some of the human con- tent of the phrases of control. What are some of the wants and feelings on which the propaganda is based? A start might be made by setting down a few general heads under which to group the workers* feelings about industry. The worker's interests in industry are roughly these ; — (1) How much he gets — Wages, etc. (2) What it's for— The Object of the Work. (3) How he's treated — ^Freedom and Author- ity. (4) What he actually does — ^Workmanship. To put these down in a row is not to pretend that " See Note on Sources. 20 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL they are equal or even sharply distinct, but the classification will serve as a tool in the examina- tion and comparison of some of the elements in the demand for control. The first two sets of interests are concerned with the consumption of the products of industry, the others with the con- ditions of production. The third and fourth in- terests fit closely the issues of discipline and management which are the frontier of control. The first and second apparently bear less directly on the personal and technical organization of pro- duction. But no serious study could ignore the cross-relationships between all four sets of mo- tives. How much the worker gets — in wages, hours of leisure, etc. — is of course the chief field of trade union activity.^" The immediate bargain for hours and wages is ruled out of the subsequent descrip- tions of the extent of control. But most of the complicated forms of control are themselves merely elaborate safeguards of the standard of living. Most of the control already won by the workers is control as a bulwark of wages. The checkweighman is there to see that wages are '" The annual official Reports on Strikes and Lockouts give figures of the numbers of workpeople involved in disputes and a classification of the disputes according to the issues involved. According to these, 64 per cent of the workpeople out in the years 1901-13 were out over (question of wages and hours. See Note on Sources. THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 21 not nibbled away by fraud.^^ Apprenticeship and similar restrictions are frankly for purposes of wage monopoly." The constitution of the Amal- gamated Society of Engineers talks of the "vested interest" in craft rights. Consultation over changes in technique is mainly an outgrowth of the piece-rate bargain.^' It is only a slight exag- geration to say that all present forms of workers' control, except those that secure the rudiments of decency in discipline, are by-products of the wages-and-hours struggle. The wage element is the dominant factor in present-day control. But what are its bearings on the demands for more control? There are at least three widely different interrelations to be noticed. The first and most talked-of is opposition. The average workman, it is often said, is interested in "mere wages." ^* He cares nothing about con- trol; he doesn't want to run things. What he wants is to draw his pay regularly and get away as quickly as possible. Nor is this merely an "Section XI. " Section V. " Section XIV. " I do not intend the phrase "mere wages" to carry any moral stigma. It is not argued that it is sordid or immoral to want wages and short hours and a steady job, and gloriously moral to want control and personal dignity and an interesting task. Nor is it argued that it is natural and healthy for men to want money and decent ventilation, but unnatural and sentimental for them to desire freedom and joy in work. The question is not what people should want but the sufficiently difficult one of what people do want. 22 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL employer's view of working-class psychology. I heard it also from an impatient leader of shop stewards who said that most workmen were **not interested beyond wages and hours" and that therefore he *'had no intention of waiting for the majority." It is true that the wage and control movements are sometimes in competition, and no doubt on a straight vote between wages and con- trol wages would still win. But it is a great mistake to suppose that the two interests are always or even usually in opposi- tion. The short-run economic interest — what R. F. Hoxie called the demand for ''more now" — is indifferent to control movements. The longer-run economic demands — which take shape in the plan- ning of drastic changes in the distribution of wealth — may on the other hand be found greatly strengthening the demand for workers' control. In fact, the latter form a major part of the driv- ing force of current control movements. The shop stewards are emphatic on this point. ''What we want," a Sheffield leader told me promptly, "is the product of the industry, and" — after hesitat- ing a moment — "conditions," by which he meant chiefly protection from trade diseases. Mr. Frank Hodges of the Miners has been perhaps the clearest of all labor leaders in his insistence on the need for control as an "avenue for great" — and non-economic — "longings." Yet he too de- THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 23 clares that the control demand is mainly one for satisfactions outside working hours: — "Workers' control is a means, and not an end. Work in the modern industrial world is unpleasant for the majority of workers. They will find their ex- pression as human beings outside the working hours. . . . Control they will use to get efficient manage- ment and machinery. . . . Control they wish to save them from the waste and insecurity and long hours of the present system . . . which leaves no secure and creative leisure. . . . But control will never of itself be an answer to the instincts thwarted by stan- dardized machine industry. The answer will be found outside working hours. ' ' ^' The demand for high pay may strengthen tlio demand for control. The desire for sure pay — for security against unemployment — is even nearer the surface of control schemes. This is in fact the chief immediate appeal to the workers of such an elaborate plan of control as the Foster Report.^* Indeed, several working-class students have told me that the desire for security is the chief factor in the demand for control. Both security and high wages might conceivably be won without workers' control, but the demands for them furnish much of the impetus of current movements toward control. Quoted by Arthur Gleason, What the Workers Want. See below, p. 86. And cf. all of Section IV. 24. THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL There is still a third interrelation between the wage motive and the ''non-economic factors" in the demand for control. What starts as a wage demand may easily — often unconsciously — ^be colored by an admixture of other motives. The clearest case is the transition in motive from wages to workmanship to be discussed in Section XV. Every demand on the part of the Miners for improved technique has had as its basis the effect of bad management on piece-work earnings. The first and obvious motive was wages. Yet a large part of the feeling with which I have heard indi- vidual miners talk about needed improvements was clearly — whether they knew it or not — a sheer workmanlike disgust at inefificiency. And at the Miners' Conference on output committees, held in November, 1916, the Yorkshire leader, Mr. Her- bert Smith, declared: — "I say it has nothing to do with it . . . whether a man gets 15 shillings or 20 shillings . . . oppor- tunity must be given . . . to get as many tubs as possible." The strictly economic motives, then, are found both opposing and greatly strengthening, and oc- casionally even passing bodily over into, the non- economic factors in the demand for control. Clearly they are not the whole demand, but any estimate of the future of the demand is worthless THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 25 if it does not consider on which side their great weight is likely to fail. Certain of the motives centering around the object for which the work is done or the purpose for which the product is to be used — what it's for and for whose benefit — have a bearing on control. The good economic man, it is true, in an imper- sonal economic system cares for none of these things. But actual workers sometimes do. The patriotic motive made a difference in war-time pro- duction. Moreover workers sometimes refuse to do certain pieces of work because they disagree with the purposes of it: — the Sailors' Union dur- ing the war would not carry delegates to the Stockholm International Labor Conference; more recently certain trade unionists have refused to make munitions for the Russian Campaign. More to the present point is the extent to which the control demand is fortified by the objection to working for private profit. The organization of industry is right enough as it is, one shop steward told me, what we want is to eliminate private ownership. The Foster Report names as one of four causes of restriction of output, *'the disin- clination of the workmen to make unlimited profit for private employers. " " We don 't want to work any longer for private profit, ' ' was the burden of the Miners' case before the Coal Commission. 26 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL That this was more than a wage matter and clearly- bound up with state socialist or community feel- ing, comes out clearly in a passage in the cross- examination of Mr. Straker of the Northumber- land Miners by Mr. Cooper of the Northumber- land Coalowners: — "Mr. Straker. . . . He [the miner] objects to those profits being collected by any few individuals. Mr. Cooper. What possible difference can it make to him whether the profits are colleeted by few or many, or by a neutral body like the State, so long as he gets his fair share? Mr. Straker. Because he is realizing now that he is a citizen of the State." The feeling is evidently in part that the status of "public servant" is somehow honorable in it- self. It is no accident that the two strongest official trade union movements toward control — those of the Miners ' Federation and the National Union of Railwayman — are for "nationalization and joint control. ' ' There is no doubt that the older social- ist feeling is a powerful element in the control demand. One careful working class student, in defining the essence of the demand for control, said that it was: "To serve the community, not a man and a class." The blending is not logically necessary. Socialist Utopias have been planned with no thought of workers ' control. The interest in what happens to the product of industry does THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 27 not necessarily involve an interest in the internal control of the production. But in the ideas of the British labor movement, at least, these two sets of motives are inextricably mingled. When Mr. Straker says that the miner must ''feel that the industry is being run by him in order to pro- duce coal for the use of the community/' it would be hard for him to say where the one motive ends and the other begins. How the worker is treated — what sort of author- ity he is under, how much freedom he is allowed, how much authority he has — on these questions the demand for control becomes most nearly a de- mand for control for control's sake. ''The con- flict of interests between employers and employed in private industry has two aspects," writes Mr. Henry Clay in the Observer, "the purely economic aspect of wages, and the moral aspect of subor- dination to discipline." There is no lack of testimony to the importance of the discipline as- pect in present-day labor feeling. Self-respect, status, independence, personal freedom, personal dignity, — a whole propaganda literature and a whole set of commentaries on labor have been written around these terms. And the roots of this sort of feeling run far back into the older trade unionism. Trade union membership, says the constitution of the Friendly Society of Iron- 28 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL founders, ' ' enables men to exhibit the principle of self-respect which, if duly exercised, will in its turn command the respect of others, thereby plac- ing a man in that position where he may demand that he should be treated as a factor in any arrangement involving his services, and not as though he was a mere human machine." A re- cent account of a dispute carried on by the shop stewards at a Cowes aircraft factory runs in al- most the same terms: — "A mass-meeting of all sections made it quite clear that they were going to insist that any attempt to treat any group of men without regard to their feelings or self-respect would be treated as a challenge to all the unions. ' ' Lord Robert Cecil put the case to the House of Commons in the phrases of political theory: — "What is really the position of the wage-earner in most industries? He is paid so much wages. He is a mere item. He has to carry out a certain industrial policy on which he has never been consulted, and with which he has no power of dealing at all. He is not really a free, self-governing man in industrial matters. ... It [this feeling] is really at the bottom of this claim for nationalization." I Professor Edwin Cannan put the same claim into homelier language in his testimony before the Coal Commission : — THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 29 * * It is all right to work with anyone ; what is disagree- able is to feel too distinctly that you are working under someone. You suffer from this feeling when you are told to do what you know, or think you know, to be the wrong thing, and also when you are told to do the right thing in a disagreeable manner." Dr. Cannan's shrewd analysis makes a good beginning for an attempt to separate out the ele- ments of the freedom-authority demand. The most conspicuous is surely the objection to be- ing told in a disagreeable manner, to being told the wrong way. It is just this that the "Welsh colliers and the railwaymen and the other workers described in Section X are ''quick to resent." Being told the wrong way is almost an exact trans- lation of "alleged harassing conduct of a fore- man," and the great number of disputes on this head is a sign of the strength of the feeling. The aircraft-workers already quoted were demanding ' ' the right to work under a manager who will real- ize that men are men inside the shop, and not servile slaves." Similar evidence of the intensity of this resentment against harsh discipline may be taken from a writer whose sympathies are entirely on the employers' side. The author of The Mam^Power of the Nation " is warning fore- men of "The Pitfalls of the Promoted":— " See Note on Sources. 30 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL "Domination, even when veneered by a display of sympathy, tends to active guardianship of privileges cherished by the worker and the exercise of that will- fulness which finds expression too often in an enforce- ment of selfish rights. In fact, were one to probe deeply into the basal cause of many disputes in works, it would be found that in a large number of cases a little thoughtfulness and tact on the part of the fore- man would have nipped the trouble in the bud." There is no doubt at all that irritation at ''petty tyranny or constant bullying" is '*at the bottom of some of the bitterest strikes." All these hot protests against particular abuses of authority are perhaps not yet a demand for con- trol. There is certainly a distinction between the resentment against being controlled in a certain way and the resentment against being controlled at all. But even more significant than the distinc- tion is the fact that the one passes so readily over into the other. The objection to being ''messed about" by an unusually fussy foreman becomes an objection to being "messed about" by any sort of supervision. The fierce resentment against ill- treatment by a particular "gafiFer" or boss crystallizes into the general phrases "sack the gaffer" or "eliminate the bosses." Resentment at being given orders in a disagreeable manner be- comes, as Cannan suggests, the general resent- ment at feeling too distinctly under orders at all. THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 31 Much of the touchiness of the workers toward the display of authority comes very near to resent- ment against all control. *'The British attitude," said the secretary of a powerful employers' asso- ciation, '*is this : — I know how to do my job and won't be told how." ** Policing" is pretty generally resented. And sometimes the objection is put rigorously into practice, as in the case of the Scottish miners who refuse to work while the overman is in their stall ^® or of the Clyde black- smiths who would not let their managing director watch their jfires.^" All this is not the demand for control in the sense of an explicit theory of opposi- tion to authority and only a small minority of the workers hold any such complete theory. But this resentment may easily be the ** makings" of such a demand. One of the shop stewards declared vehemently : — "People talk as if the demand for control was some- thing that had to be created among the workers by a slow process, hut it's there already!" He must surely have meant, however, that it was "there" in the shape of a latent resentment that might be focused on this or that particular issue, not * * there " as a fully conscious program. There is some evidence, too, of the workings of this pro- cess by which irritation with certain orders be- " See below, p. 187. " See below, p. 138, 32 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL comes a resentment against all control. A York- shire carpenter gave me a theory to account for the war-time increase in the control demand which illustrates this in detail: — Work before the war went along much the same way from year to year, and few new orders had to be given. There was nothing to make the workers especially con- scious that they were under control. The rapid war changes made necessary a sudden stream of novel and disturbing and often conflicting orders. All this made the workers feel themselves more distinctly bossed, and therefore ready to think in terms of opposition to control. The intellectual history of one of the prominent Clyde shop stewards has run a somewhat similar course. Be- fore he had any particular social theories he used to resent being watched at his work. When the manager brought guests through the shop he used to switch off the power and walk away from his machine — ''bad enough to have to work in a fac- tory anyhow without being put on exhibition do- ing it ! " It was this sensitiveness to all subordi- nation which became the basis for his later revolu- tionary theories ; and it is this, he claims, which is the real driving force in the minds of the leaders of the extremist movements. The sensitiveness of those who always ''feel too distinctly" that they are under someone is very near the core of the conscious theories of control. The feeling of THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 33 servility in subordination to the employer's authority is the leading note in shop steward prop- aganda. This is what makes the bitterness that runs through Mr. J. T. Murphy's pamphlets: — "Why are men and women servile^to directors, man- agers, and foremen? Why do men dodge behind ma- chines and in lavatories to smoke while the employers can and do stroll through the shops smoking cigars? . . . Why do men and women work long hours and show all the characteristics of subjection to the em- ployers if the latter do not possess a power over them? . . . The workers show all the characteristics of a sub- ject people when in contact with the employers."^" Mr. Straker is a labor leader of quite different temper, but the same feeling of resentment that the worker should be ** merely at the will or direc- tion of another being" " appears again and again in his testimony before the Coal Commission. The following passage is typical: — "Q. I notice that you lay considerable stress in your precis upon this idea that under the pre-war system the workmen were in what they called a servile position : do you really seriously put that forward? Mr. Straker. I do. . . . It is always a servile posi- tion when men are almost entirely under the control of another. " '* •* Compromise or Independence? See Note on Sources. " Coal Commission Evidence, Question 23116. See Note on Sources. " Questions 23433, 23434. 34 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL A resentment against the whole system of con- trol in industry, a resentment constantly fed by irritation at particular cases of clumsily-exercised control, is a genuine and distinct factor in the demands of labor. It may still be pointed out that all this is merely a negative resentment against control and not specifically a positive demand for control. This distinction may seem like an attempt to cut be- tween things never separated in practice, but it is not merely a quibble. The desire to be let alone, to be free from the irksomeness of control by others, is not identical with the desire to co-oper- ate actively in the work of controlling. The ''will to be responsible for oneself" does not automati- cally resolve itself into the will to take part in representative government. The question of how far and under what conditions the one passes over into the other is a highly important practical point. Men might be ungovernable by authority without being thereby ready to govern themselves. The demand for personal freedom within in- dustry is not identical with the demand for political power within industry ; the one begins as a desire for no government, the other is a desire for a share in self-government. How much of the latter is there in the present-day control demand? Clearly it is a less vocal part. The roots and beginnings of the control demand are in the felt THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 35 irksomeness of the present system of control, not in a conscious desire for a new field of activity. I heard a group of Derbyshire miners thrashing out the problem. *' Supervision is nauseous." On that they heartily agreed. ''But supervision is necessary." Yes, if only for safety. Then one of the men suggested that there might be another sort of supervision — ''amicable discipline" he called it — in which the supervisors should be elected by and responsible to the workers. It is apparently in some such way as this that the positive demand arises. Mr. Frank Hodges is almost alone in putting the demand for responsi- bility— for the ' ' daily exercise of directive ability" — in the forefront of the claim for control. Little direct evidence of the reality of this demand can be taken from industry itself. What interest the ordinary workman may have had in running things or in managing men has had to be satisfied out- side of industry if at all. Evidence from the few firms that have experimented with the "devolu- tion of managerial functions ' ' is conflicting. Some report an almost pathetic pleasure over consulta- tion on very minor matters,®^ some a real interest in general policy, some a refusal to take responsi- bility. Perhaps a better judgment of the interest of workers in "running things" might be formed from a study of their organizing activities outside •• Cf., p. 191. 36 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL the workshop, — the Trade Union Movement itself, with the remarkable series of experiments and failures and successes in devising forms of organization which make (or should make) the two great books of the Webbs books for the political scientist; the Co-operative Movement, with what D. F. Schloss called **its power to pro- mote the organization upon democratic lines of the working classes by the working classes"; the Dissenting Chapels, in regard to which Mrs. Webb wrote of *'the debt which English democracy owes to the magnificent training given by Protes- tant Dissent in the art of self-government;" the national and local work of the Labor Party; and so on. The question runs beyond the scope of the present study. The extent and range of working class organizations may be put on one side, the poor attendance at trade union meetings ^* and the low percentage of votes cast on important trade union ballots on the other. Some organizing in- terest is surely "there," in the shop steward's phrase ; the important question is really whether or not it will be turned inwards upon industry it- self. These demands that bear directly upon the ques- tion of authority are of the highest importance in a study of the control problem. Control is a •* " To get an attendance of 70 to 100 out of a branch member- ship of 300 to 1000 is a sign of stirring times, or of unemploy- ment," says Mr. J. T. Murphy. THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 37 political ^^ word. The demands previously studied are not primarily political; they are concerned with the control of industry not as an end but as a possible means, and they might conceivably be satisfied without changes in workshop politics. But the "political" demands now under discus- sion are concerned more nearly with control for its own sake ; their chance of satisfaction depends directly ^^ upon the type of industrial government. These "political" demands may be phrased as the demand not to he controlled disagreeably, the demand not to he controlled at all, and the demand to take a hand in controlling. The first runs through all trade union activity. The second is less widespread. The conscious general resent- ment is vastly less than the sum of particular irri- tations, but it is the powerful driving passion of the control agitation. The third — the desire for a share in the job of running things — is real but less immediate. The force of these freedom demands is hard to measure. Apparently they run as an under- current in many of labor's campaigns on other issues. It is impossible to judge the extent to which a vague and uneasy sense of oppression *' " Political," that is, in the wide sense of concerned with au- thority relationships ; not " political " in the narrow sense of relating to the authority of the State of territorial unit. " Except in so far as the organizing interest is drawn off into non-industrial channels. 38 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL adds to the bitterness and determination with which apparently trivial disputes are fought. It is by now a commonplace " to say that the occa- sion or formulated issue of a strike, as of a war, is only a part of its cause or of the emotions that are called out; surely a part of the emotion that gathers around any industrial struggle is that of servant against master. It is in this sense that Mr. Straker calls **the straining of the will of man to be free" the root cause of labor unrest. And it is the linking of this feehng with the economic motive that makes ** wage- slavery" a powerful phase for propagandists to conjure with. These political factors are rightly thought of as the essential part of the demand for control. Possibly they are not the strongest part of the demand, but they are the part least likely to be diverted from the issue of the government of in- dustry. They are the core of the demand; the other motives may in various circumstances be added unto it. The worker's interests in the work itself — in what he actually/ does, in the technical processes of industry — have also important bearings on the control problem. Cannan's analysis of the resent- ment against control includes both "political" and •^ Thanks in part to the work of the late Carleton Parker. THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 39 technical factors. The ''feeling when you are told to do what you know, or think you know, to be the wrong thing," is surely a workmanlike distaste for inefficiency. The technical interests are often grouped under the one term worktnanship '®; it is safer to discuss them simply as interests in the job. The interest usually mentioned first under this head is craftsmanship, the feeling of the indi- vidual craftsman toward his own particular bit of skilled technique. And the first thing that is usually said about it is that it is dead or at least dying out.^® Certainly the long run effects of the transition from handicraft to modern ma- chine industry bear heavily in that direction. ' * In the technique of handicraft the central fact is always the individual workman." On the other hand, *'the share of the operative workman in the machine industry is (typically) that of an atten- dant, an assistant, whose duty it is to keep pace with the machine process and to help out with workmanlike manipulation at points where the machine process is incomplete."*" Crafts and craftsmanship are clearly going down together " Cf. especially Thornstein Veblen, The Instinct of Workman- ship. '•"The worst indictment of capitalism," one ex-joiner told me with unexpected bitterness. *' The Instinct of Workmanship, pp. 234, 806. The last two chapters of the book are a discussion of the institutional bearings of this technological change. 40 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL before the advance of fool-proof machinery and standardized industry. But it is much too early to count off craftsman- ship as a genuine force in industry. Nor is it strictly true to say that it survives only in the tiny remaining handicrafts or only in the trades mentioned in Section XIX under the topic of "old craft control." Even in the great industry there are occasional indications of craftsmanship — though no propagandist movement is finding it worth while to bring together evidence on the point. The best signs of it are in fact those that come out incidentally in the course of discussions on other subjects — such as the use by a certain skilled joiner of his own dexterous hands as the basis for his social theories,*^ the use by an en- gineering trades official of "cutting a micrometer scale ' ' as the type of something that required real skill, or the following passage on rate-fixing from the Ministry of Labor's report on Works Com- mittees : — **A discussion that starts about the price of a job often finishes by two men staking their reputations as craftsmen and their experience as workmen that they are absolutely right. ' ' I have even heard an engineering shop steward confess to a certain pride in the skill of the craft whose special privileges he was attacking. *'" Human hands too valuable" to be used for "donkey work." THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 41 Craftsmanship is still a force, though a dimin- ishing one. In relation to the control demand it cuts two ways. It is a conservative factor in the resistance of the old crafts against ''encroach- ments" upon their ancient forms of control.*'' It moreover is an element in stiffening the demand not to be controlled. The true craftsmen will stand very little supervision in regard to his own technique. The glass bottle maker will not work under a manager who is not trained as a glass bottle hand. ' 'I know how to do my job and won't be told how" — this was quoted as almost the cen- tral element in the demand not to be controlled. Pride in craft skill may often make a part of that independence which resists irksome control. But craftsmanship seems to cut just the other way in relation to the positive side of the control demand. The old craft unions are completely in- different to the newer ''political" demands. The craftsman may be quick to resent interference with his own work, but he is not likely to bother about organizing activities very far outside that work. "The artist, the craftsman, the scholar and the scientist have one overpowering desire; to be let alone," writes Mr. Arthur Gleason. "They haven't the slightest wish to run anything or any- body, to manage, to 'know the commercial side,' to market the product or to control the raw " See below. Section XIX. 42 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL material." It is true that some of the control propaganda — notably that of one school of Guild Socialists — runs in terms of a return to crafts- manship; but the immediate program of workers' control is a program of opportunities for political activity within large-scale industry. If Professor Wallas is at all right in making ''concentration on what he can see and touch" the essential characteristic of the craftsman,*' it is no use for National Guildsmen to talk arts and crafts and at the same time to point to the Miners' Federation of Great Britain and the National Union of Rail- waymen as promising steps "Towards National Guilds." Craftsmanship has no direct connection with representative government. By its concen- tration on the immediate and highly individual skill it runs counter to the general organizing interest which makes up the positive side of the demand to exercise control, biit by the very pride in that individual skill it stiffens the refusal to be controlled. So much for the relation of craftsmanship to control. But the chances of interest in the work for the work's sake do not end with individual manual craftsmanship. The enthusiastic manag- ing director of a great engineering firm may have as keen an interest in the process of production as any Swiss wood carver. Large-scale ' ' social pro- ** Graham Wallas, The Great Society, p. 4. THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 43 duction" has to a great extent taken the place of individual production. With it have come a set of interests in the technique of group-organi- zation as well as in the technique of individual work. Collective workmanship might serve as a general term for them, but the interests covered would run from an interest in the routing of work in a particular shop to an interest in the governing and lay-out of great industrial enterprises. Some of these feelings — that of the individual in- ventor,** for example, or the pride in a great in- dustry,*^ or the queer generalized pride in being "practical men"*" and ''industrialists" — ^bear only indirectly on the demand for control. At least one interest, the pride in a particular firm's workmanship — ^Wedgwood's in the Potteries is one of a few cases — ^may run counter to the con- trol demands. But certain of these interests in collective work appear directly as part of the control demand. The most conspicuous of these is the demand for the right to make suggestions about the con- duct of the work. Of the reality of this interest there is abundant evidence.*^ A foreman in one of "But cf., pp. 217-219. " But note the use of the pride in "the industry as a national service" in the Buildin? Trades Parliament. *• It would be amusing to count the number of times this phrase is used, both by employers and workers, in a year's crop of arbitration proceedings and blue books on labor problems. *'See Section XVI. 44 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL the National Factories *^ was telling me how the management had encouraged suggestions both from the foremen's and the workers' committees. *'It isn't only the big wages," he declared em- phatically. **The men like to have their ideas taken up. ' ' In discussing the demand for control with a group of Derbyshire miners, I found — to my surprise — that this was the issue on which they showed the greatest interest. One man got up and declared: — "There isn't a man in this room who hasn't time and again made suggestions and been told he was paid not to think but to work." The evening turned into a sort of testimony meeting in which the men related different specific suggestions that they had made, and the next noon the colliery blacksmith stopped me on the road to explain to me how he thought his company might use compressed air more efficiently, and sa on. This interest in making suggestions — and the strong feeling that the chance to make them is blocked under the present type of industrial gov- ernment— are real factors in the demand for con- trol. The interest in making suggestions, moreover, can hardly be separated from the interest in see- ing those suggestions put into force. It is in fact *' Munition plants run directly by the Government. THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 45 only a special form of a general interest in the running of modem industry. Various traces of an interest in the technical efficiency of industry may be found in labor feeling. There is at least a certain negative interest, a disgust with various sorts of inefficiency. Evidence is hard to collect since, as a building trades union official remarked, most of the discussions of workmen on a job about the inefficiency of their employers can find no outlet in the form of suggestions.*^ One of the Derbyshire miners just quoted talked of being ''told to do the silliest things imaginable." A Clyde shop steward told me that a disgust with the inefficiencies of management was always there for the agitator to ''play on" — evidence the more interesting because the object of the agita- tion was certainly not to stir up technical interest. How widespread this sense of irritation with in- efficiencies in organization may be, it is impossible to say. Its clearest expression is in the complaints of the Miners, enforced by trade union power, against inefficiencies in the arrangements for haulage, etc."" Nor does this interest always re- main merely negative. There are even cases of the urging of positive changes in organization. This is shown in the elaborate schemes of the '•See Section XVI for the results in a few cases where an otitlet has been provided. "See Section XV. 46 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL Post Office Workers for extending the financial side of the postal service, of which one of their leaders speaks as follows: — * ' The workers want to take part in the administration of the Department. For years past they have proffered suggestions whereby the public could be better served and the services more efficiently organized and man- aged, but they have been turned down." It is shown in the detailed suggestions on the technique of the industry presented to the Coal Commission by the Miners' Federation. What Justice Sankey called the Miners' "higher am- bition of taking their due share and interest in the direction of the industry," is, as he realized, of great significance. It marks the appearance of the managing and planning interest as a definite factor in the control demand. Workmanship in this most general sense is an idea that has run through part of the propaganda of workers' control ever since the agitation of 1911. One of Mr. Mann's followers declared that year : — "I for one believe we have yet to see good work, and that will be when work is made pleasant and attractive, well organized by capable men, who will have been elected by their mates. ... I understand Syndicalism is to use some of its efforts at making the worker take a vital interest in the industry he is connected with, THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 47 thereby preparing him for the democratic control of the industrial community of the future." The most comprehensive statement of the work- manship part of the demand — and one that adds to it the demand for knowledge about large-scale industry — is given in Mr. Straker's testimony before the Coal Commission on March 13, 1919 : — "Any administration of the mines, under nationaliza- tion, must not leave the worker in the position of a mere wage-earner, whose whole energies are directed by the will of another. He must have a share in the manage- ment of the industry in which he is engaged, and un- derstand all about the purpose and destination of the product he is producing; he must know both the pro- ductive and the commercial side of the industry. He must feel that the industry is being run by him in order to produce coal for the use of the community, instead of profit for a few people. He would thus feel the responsibility which would rest upon him as a citi- zen, and direct his energies for the common good. This ideal cannot be reached all at once, owing to the way in which private ownership has deliberately kept the worker in ignorance regarding the industry; but as that knowledge which has been denied him grows, as it will do under nationalization, he will take his right- ful place as a man. Only then will labor unrest, which is the present hope of the world, disappear." This explicit plea for the chance of workmanship is the demand of a few. When Mr. Ben Turner, 48 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL the veteran leader of the Textile Workers, put the question at the Trades Union Congress; — ''Why shouldn't they sing at their work?" the cheers were more out of pleasure in his personality than from any very definite notion of work that might be worth singing about. The Right of Workman- ship is not carried as a motto on the street banners of the labor movement. These various interests in the job tie back to all the other factors of the control demand. A striking case of the substitution of the workman- ship for the wage motive has already been men- tioned. The last statement quoted from Mr. Straker's evidence is one of many that show the blending of the public service and workmanship interests. The relations between the freedom and workmanship demands are even more central to the control problem. Craftsmanship has already been spoken of as strengthening the objection to being controlled, and surely all forms of work- manship fortify what Mr. Cole calls * ' the natural impulse we all feel to push aside anyone whom we see doing badly what we can do better." The feeling of inferiority which deepens the bitterness of the agitation for control is in part a feeling of functional inferiority. It is impossible to separate the ''organizing interest" spoken of as the posi- tive side of the "political" demand from the interests in organizing industry just discussed. THE DEMAND FOR CONTROL 49 In fact it is just where the two are one that the control demand is the clearest. The general interest in organization becomes directly impor- tant for control only when it is turned to the organ- izing of industry ; the general interests in industry become directly important for control only as they become organizing interests. In a list of the nucleus elements of the demand for control — those elements, that is, that can hardly be diverted from the issue of the control of industry — it is necessary to put with the ''political" factors of the determination of workers not to he run and their desire to rum things the ** workmanship" addition that it is industry that workers want to run. This is indeed implied in the quotation which began this introduction. Mr. Straker, it is true, states the demand in terms of ''the straining of the will of men to be free ; ' ' but he has more than once explained that he means by that not merely a negative freedom but a positive freedom, a free- dom to do something. The content of his idea of freedom is in fact workmanship. It would, I think, be fair to his position to rephrase it as follows : — ■ I Wages and conditions are not enough. They have been improved and the unrest is still strong. Mere negative freedom from harsh discipline is not enough. That tjifi Northumberland Miners have long been able to secure and the unrest is still strong. The root of the 50 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL matter is a demand for a pasitive freedom of responsi- bility a/nd self-expression. But such a clear-cut claim for control is the claim of a tiny minority. Most of the driving force of the movement comes from other motives, and no single statement can pretend to express all the confused strivings that make up the total demand. The whole of this introduction makes only a be- ginning at describing its complexity. The actual demand for control is a tangle of half -expressed and shifting and richly varied desires. That is, it is a human phenomenon. It is a dogma in the somewhat Early Christian faith of the Clyde shop stewards that "the fer- ment creates its own organization. " It is at least ''ferment" that makes ''organization" interest- ing. And it is the ferment of the demand for control that makes worth while a patient study of the present extent of control. A STUDY IN BRITISH WORKSHOP POLITICS CONTROL There is a theory current that the employer does and should exercise something that is known as ''complete executive control" over industry. There are other theories current that the organ- ized workers should — sooner or later, and more or less completely — take over ''the control of industry." Workshop politics are forcing them- selves into first place in social politics, and the workshop conflict represented by these ideas is perhaps the most significant fact in the social politics of the day. This study is an attempt to make a record of the present stage of the conflict in Great Britain in terms of the questions : — What is the present extent, and what are the boundaries, of workers' control? How much control of in- dustry do the British workers now exercise? But "control" over what? The term is used by the contestants in the struggle in an undefined but somewhat specialized sense. When one of the coal-owners on the Coal Commission asked one 51 B!^ THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL of the Miners' Executive what they meant when they said they wanted control, and the answer was: — '*We mean just what you mean when you say we must not have control," they were using a term an outsider might well try to define for himself. ''Complete executive control" might mean, among other things, that the employer "by his absolute knowledge and mere motion" provides capital, decides what to produce and how to pro- duce it, provides any sort of place to work, hires whom he likes, pays his hands any wages by any system, works them any number of hours he likes, drives them by any method and with any degree of supervision, promotes, fines, or dismisses them for any cause, trains any hand for any job, dic- tates every process in the minutest detail — and does all this and more "subject to change without notice." But the most cursory acquaintance with industry or a glance at a few typical collective agreements shows that the employer ^ has no such * The use of the phrase " the employer " is not meant to imply that all employers are alike either in personality or in their position in industry. But the differences between employers, great as they are, are comparatively unimportant in the present connection since they are not usually expressed in differences of the extent of control they leave to their employees. The popular distinction between " good " and " bad " employer is of no use for the present purpose, — except in so far as the " bad " employer may arouse his employees to devise means of controlling him, or as the "good" employer may also happen to believe, in Mr. Seebohm Rowntree's phrase, in "giving as much control as he can instead of as little as he must." CONTROL 53 control as this. The real question is how much less does he mean by ''complete executive control." There is after all such a thing as a trade union and, as Professor Commons says, ''If it cannot prevent the employer from doing as he pleases at some point or other, it is something besides a trade union." But the question is, which points? What matters have been recognized as subjects for consultation, at least, rather than employer's fiat? First and most obviously, wages and hours. The "wage bargain" has always been in the eyes of the law a bargain between equals. The primary function of the trade union has been to restore to this contract some degree of real equality. These are of course the questions on which the workers now exercise their most important share of control. In the second place, some of the more obvious physical "conditions of employment" — ^ventila- tion, sanitary arrangements, and works conven- iences generally — have also long been subject both to collective bargaining and Factory Act legislation. Neither of these things, though, is control in the sense that either a fighting employer or a propagandist of "workers' control" would use the term. An employer's control over industry is not destroyed by the fact that he has to buy 64 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL labor with much the same equality in bargaining that he buys other factors in production. And matters of toilets and air space and welfare work are after all not vital to absolute power over the actual organization of production. The question of ''control" arises beyond the immediate contract of so many hours or so many pieces of work for so much pay, and beyond the obvious physical "conditions of employment," in the debatable ground where regulating the "con- ditions of employment" appears from another point of view to be actual sharing in the organiza- tion of industry. The object of the present study is to find out how much control the workers have over matters that are (1) Less immediate to the "wage bargain" it- self than Rates of Wages and Hours of Labor. (2) More immediate to the "actual business of production" than Ventilation, etc. What degree of control do the trade unions exercise over the relations of man to man in indus- try— the employment and discipline relationships ; and over the relations of man to the work itself — • to the plans, processes, and technique of industry! How much say have the workers over what the boot manufacturers once called "the internal economy of the workshop and the manipulation of the workman by the employer?" CONTROL 65 The first and obvious answer is — directly and explicitly, very little. A longer and more critical answer requires study and analysis of collective agreements and arbitration awards, of trade union regulations, of jealously guarded shop practices and customs of the trades, of the issues of strikes, and of the demands of the revolutionary minority. In theory trade union rules rarely extend beyond the ** conditions of employment" in the sense of the famous definition of the Webbs of a trade union as "a continuous association of wage-earn- ers for the purpose of maintaining or improving the conditions of their employment. ' ' ^ But it is at least worth a study of such "conditions" as the non-unionist, apprenticeship and demarcation questions; the various expedients for meeting unemployment; discipline, dismissals and the handling of grievances ; promotion and the choice and authority of foremen; methods and payment and the measurement of results; restrictions on technique; consultation over change in technique and over trade policy, etc., to determine to what extent they involve, in fact if not in form, trade union (1) interference with (2) consultation over (3) direction of the actual organization of industry. • History of Trade Unioimm, p. 1. See Note on Sources. n THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL ** Workers' control" is, I suppose, often trans- lated as ''interfering with the employer's busi- ness." A definite notion of the meaning attached to the latter phrase would be of use in finding the fighting frontier of control. Where does the issue come into the open? At what point does the employer say — ^beyond this there shall be no discussion, the rest is my business alone? The line is a hard one to draw; the issues are rarely • thought out in the abstract and rarely presented dramatically. The real frontier, like most lines in industry, is more a matter of accepted custom than of precisely stated principle. In a few in- stances, however, there have been definite at- tempts to stake out the boundary, evidently as results of disputes in which the principle became explicit. There are for example a number of collective agreements ^ that attempt to define the ''Authority of Employers ' ' in such terms as these : — "Each employer shall conduct his business in any way he may think advantageous in all details of man- * Report on Collective Agreements. See Note on Sources. 56 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL 57 agement, not infringing on the individual liberty of the workman or these rules." (Liverpool Carpenters and Joiners.) "Each employer shall have the power to conduct his business in any way he may think advantageous in the matter of letting work, taking apprentices, using ma- chinery and implements, and in all details of manage- ment not infringing these rules." (Birmingham Brick- layers.) **That Dressers shall not interfere in any way what- ever with the management of workshops." (Scottish Steel Dressers.) "The right of the Association to organize its equip- ment and to regulate its labor with a view to the lowest cost of production." (Bradford Dyers Association.) The most famous of these declarations of the employers' authority was the Engineering Trades Agreement signed in 1898 after a great and un- successful strike. This declared under the head of *' General Principle of Freedom to Employers in the Management of their Works, ' ' that : — "The Federated Employers, while disavowing any intention of interfering with the proper functions of Trade Unions, wiU admit no interference with the man- agement of their business. . . . Employers are re- sponsible for the work turned out by their machine tools, and shall have full discretion to appoint the men they consider suitable to work them, and determine the conditions under which such machine tools shall be worked." 68 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL In addition to these attempts to define positively the borderline of control there are a number of agreements which define it negatively by setting aside questions which are not matters for discus- sion. Certain questions, they say, are questions .for bargaining or arbitration; certain questions are vital and reserved to the employer. It is worth while to mention a few of these non- justiciable questions of industry. The Pottery arbitration agreement which preceded the present Joint Industrial Council ruled out the two questions of **Good from Oven" (deduction from wages for broken pots) and "Limitation of Apprentices." A Liverpool Dockers agreement provides "that the Union shall not interfere with the methods of working cargo on ships or quay." Leicester Boot and Shoe arbitration arrangements provide that "no Board shall interfere with the right of an employer to make reasonable regulations for time- keeping and the preservation of order in his fac- tory or workshop." The last rule of a pioneer "Works Committee in the woollen industry reads : "It is understood and agreed that it is the business of the management, and is not the business of the Con- ference to deal with: — (a) The allocation of work to particular sets of drawing. (b) The allocation of winders to particular ma- chines. ' ' THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL 59 More typical, however, are provisions such as the following : — "Questions of discipline and management not to be interfered with." (London Motor Bus Employees.) Under questions to be discussed: — "Differences relat- ing to general conditions of labor (not being questions of discipline and management)." (London County Council Tramways.) Arbitration on "any question other than one which he [the arbitrator] shall decide to relate to manage- ment and discipline." (Bobbin Turners, etc., at Garton and Coverholme.) The phrase *' discipline and management" has been made most prominent by its appearance in the remarkable succession of railway crises. Dur- ing the ** all-grades movement" of 1907, which turned on the issue of union recognition, Mr. -Robert Bell, the Secretary of the Railway Serv- ants, was ''on all occasions most emphatic in denying that it was the desire of the men's execu- tive committee to interfere with the discipline of the railway staffs," while Lord Claud Hamilton (who wanted his men **to be free and independent as subjects of a Constitutional Monarch") and other railway directors were firm in their ** abso- lute refusal to allow the society to interfere in our domestic relations with our staff." The Concilia- 60 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL tion Boards, set up in that year as Mr. Lloyd George's solution of the difficulty, were expressly limited to the consideration of "rates of wages and hours of labor." By the time of the railway strike of 1911, the attitude of the men was changed. When their leaders testified before the Royal Commission of that year, they were no longer willing to repeat the absolute denial of an interest in discipline. Mr. J. H. Thomas in fact argued that, ''the common sense of two parties meeting in a representative capacity is more likely to arrive at a right decision than through one side's taking up the attitude that it is purely a question for them to determine. . . . The men are distinctly of opinion that all questions ought to be discussed and settled by the Board. ' ' The Commission, how- ever, reported that "with their great responsibili- ties the companies cannot and should not be ex- pected to permit any intervention between them and their men on the subjects of discipline and management ; ' ' and by the 1911 scheme, although the companies are to receive deputations on "any questions affecting the contractual relations be- tween the company and its employees," the Boards themselves are limited to consideration of "rates of wages, hours of labor, or conditions of service, other than matters of management and discipline." Since that time the last clause has been the storm center of the industry^ and the dis- THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL 61 satisfaction with it is now expressed in a demand for nationalization with joint control by the workers and the State. ''Discipline and management," then, has often summed up the issue of control. The phrase would perhaps most often be used by an employer to describe the issues over which he would refuse to share control. And, from the other side, the president of the National Union of Railwaymen declares that, ''it is in the fierce questions of dis- cipline and management," that his union has found its soul. But when one has said that discipline and man- agement are the crux of the control problem, one is not very far along. The phrase almost disap- pears under analysis. The specific issues that have come under what the Railway Review calls "the symbols D and M" include such things as dismissals, promotions, classification of employees, a doubtful safety regulation, etc. The Steel Dres- sers agreement quoted above goes on to include under the reservations to management the alloca- tion of work between classes of workmen. The Engineering agreement put in the same category the selection, training, and employment of opera- tives and the right to pay according to ability. And in 1907 the Railway Gazette even argued that if wages and hours were "fixed by two dif- ferent bodies" {i.e. by negotiation with a union) ^ th;e FRt)¥rriEii op control sm impossible ' ''dtia^lity of ^anagetnelat ^wmld arise 1" But ^11 tkese q^aestiofis have of course been subjects for . F. Schloss defined in 1891^ as involving three principles, of which the second is of interest here : — (1) Workers associated by free choice. (2) Workers under a leader elected and removable hy themselves. (3) Pay divided among members of group on princi- ples recognized by themselves as equitable. He gave interesting examples of this practice, but they were for the most part only on the very fringes of "the great industry," in such indus- ^Methodg of Industrial Remuneration. 120 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL trial pockets as the Cornish tin mines, and the practice has since his time fallen still further into disuse. Both these examples of co-operative work and the examples of election of foremen referred to here are taken from a sort of industry in which it is possible for the foreman to be a fellow- worker with his men and to represent them in bargain- ing as well as to supervise their work. They amount in effect to a democratic form of sub- contract, and together with other forms of sub- contract they seem to be giving away before the standardizing process of large-scale modern in- dustry. There is, then, some body of experience of trade union control over the choice of foremen in a number of the older crafts. Is there any trade union control over the choice of foremen in ''the great industry" itself, in the modern large-scale, carefully- regimented industries where the strain of superintendence is the greatest? The answer can be almost a direct ''no." I have been able to find no instance in which the workers in modern- ized industry have either the recognized right of election of foremen or the formal right of veto- ing an unpopular selection. Instances even of consultation over the choice are extremely rare, even in cases where the works committees dis- cuss a fairly wide range of subjects. Messrs. Hans Eenold, Ltd., chain manufacturers with a THE CHOICE OF FOREMEN 121 large factory just outside Manchester, make a practice of announcing the choice of a foreman to the shop stewards ' committee and explaining their reasons for it before publication of the announce- ment. Messrs. Rowntree & Sons, Ltd., at their cocoa works at York, allow this discussion to take place before the decision is actually reached and (presumably) allow it to influence the decision. Their precise rule on this point, which was adopted by their Works Council in the spring of 1919 after the workers ' side had brought in a proposal which came much nearer direct election, is as follows : — ' ' That before any person is appointed as an overlooker, the name of such person shall be submitted to a Com- mittee of the workers on the Department Council, but the final decision regarding the appointment will con- tinue to rest with the Director of the Department. ' ' These very minor exceptions are perhaps chiefly of importance as showing how definite a princi- ple it is in the constitutional theory of modern industry — if there is any such thing — that the workers are excluded from any control over the choice of their supervisors. It is impossible, however, to break oif the dis- cussion at this point for two reasons: — First, there is already an organized opposition to this theory — the desire for a say in the choice of fore- men is a serious factor in the demands of labor. 122 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL Second, the theory, like other constitutional theories, in practice does not at all work out to the letter— the workers have now more say in the choice of foremen than any formal agreement sug- gests. The best evidence on the first point — that the choice of foremen has already become to some extent an open question — is the discussion in the Works Committees report of the Ministry of Labor : — "The appointment of foremen is a question on which there may be said to be three groups of opinions. Many employers hold that it is purely a management question. The opposite extreme to this is the claim made by a con- siderable section of Trade Unionists that the workmen should choose their own foremen. A position inter- mediate to these two extremes is taken up by a certain number of employers and by a section of workpeople; the appointment (they feel) should be made by the management, but it should be submitted to the Works Council before it becomes effective.' Even this intermedi- ate position, however, is not really a common position; there are differences of opinion as to the conditions under which the appointment should come before the Works Committee — that is to say, whether or not the Works Committee should have power to veto the appointment." (pp. 33-34) Mr. Cole and other Guild Socialists speak of the election of foremen as *'one of the next steps." The principle — or a step towards it — has been em- bodied in several schemes suggested by groups THE CHOICE OF FOREMEN 123 of workers. One suggestion now being elabo- rated is that of a panel system — ^under which the workers' committee should nominate a list of candidates for a vacancy from which the employer should choose one. Messrs. Gallacher & Paton of the Clyde engineering shop stewards, have sug- gested^ a system of ** collective contracts" under which ''the Convenors of the Works Committee and the Departmental Committee would gradually but surely drive out and sup- plant the Works Manager and Departmental Foreman." Many such proposals make a dis- tinction between officials who are primarily ''man- managers," whose chief duty is the supervision of workers, and those who are primarily tech- nicians; and it is with the choice of the former that the schemes are concerned. On the other hand, a detailed set of proposals for the future control of the mines, put forward by the same group of extremists who wrote the Mmers' Next Step, in- sists that even the definitely technical officials should be directly elected, with the proviso that candidates must possess the technical certificates of qualification now necessary. "The one essen- tial condition of our plan is the democratic elec- tion of all officials." It is not worth while to set out these schemes in detail at this point ; they are referred to as an evidence of an articulate * See below, p. 173, and Note on Sources. 124 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL opposition to the exclusion of workers from a say in the choice of their supervisors. It is more important to point out that the workers do often actually exercise more power over the choice of foremen than any agreement suggests. At one Manchester motor works a particularly active shop stewards' committee had been making trouble for a succession of foremen ; finally the firm in despair said, * ' Choose your own foreman, then," and they did. This is only an extreme instance of a sort of control which is not uncommon. At the height of their power during the war, the Clyde shop stewards, while they claimed no right to choose foremen, could ''make it impossible" for an unpopular foreman. The extent to which the workers make it impossible for foremen to whom they object — and therefore exercise a clumsy and delayed but real and very important veto over the choice of foremen— will be considered in Section X. It was of veto in their sense rather than of veto by formal right that Mr. Cole spoke in his testimony before the Coal Commission : — ' * The extent to which trade unions exercise an amount of control over the selection of foremen negatively by veto is increasing very fast." (Question 13169) And it is this sort of veto that makes the most important limit to the power of the employer to select supervisors at will. THE CHOICE OF FOREMEN 125 ** Control over employers, foremen, etc. . . . is," said D. F. ScMoss, ** aimed at by the essen- tial principles of Trade Unionism. ' ' Yet workers ' control over foremen by direct election is practi- cally non-existent in the great industry. This, however, by no means exhausts all possible forms of control in the field. There are at least two further methods by which the workers exert con- trol over their supervisors, — first, by pressure through the trade union if the supervisor belongs to the same or to a friendly union; and second, by the refusal to work under intolerable super- vision or objectionable supervisors. These methods of control will be the subjects of the next two sections. IX THE ORGANIZATION OF FOREMEN The organization of foremen, like all questions of trade union structure, is of interest for this in- quiry only as it affects trade union function in the direction of control. But it is evident that the extent of control by workers over their im- mediate supervisors depends in part on the an- swers to the questions: — Are these supervisors organized at all? Are they organized in the same unions as the workers under them? Are they organized in separate unions? And are these last friendly or hostile to the other unions? Trade union practice in regard to the inclusion of foremen within the same unions as the workers under them is varied and is complicated by a number of motives. The ''friendly benefit" side of trade unionism tends to hold a man in his union after he has been promoted to the foreman's job. Conscious trade union policy on the question has been affected by two contradictory principles: — Don't trust them: Capture them. The idea behind the former is that the workman by accepting promotion has stepped across a defi- 126 THE ORGANIZATION OF FOREMEN 127 nite line and has become the employer's man. From that time on he is bargaining for the em- ployer and against the worker; therefore he must not be trusted with any news of the workers' plans. He is the **guv'nor's man" and therefore no longer ''safe." The natural outcome of this feeling is to exclude foremen from the union, or at least to let them remain only as honorary mem- bers or for purposes of friendly benefit, as the Glass Bottle Workers do by their rule that *'a walking manager may remain a member of the society, but shall not be allowed to attend any meetings without being specially summoned." This attitude has been the general one in the past. ** Foremen, deputies, superintendents, and the like," writes Mr. Cole,^ "are naturally for the most part promoted from the ranks of the Trade Union Movement. . . It is true that throughout the history of Trade Unionism a certain number of such promoted workmen have retained their connection with their Trade Unions in a more or less private manner, by being attached to Cen- tral Office Branches, and by other similar de- vices ; but even where this has been the case they have usually lost all share in the government of their Societies." The opposing idea is that having your foreman in your own union is a good way of making sure ' G. D. H. Cole, An Introduction to Trade Unionitm, p. 72. 128 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL that he won't treat you unjustly. The public opinion of the union is counted on to enforce upon its supervising numbers a standard of decency in the treatment of subordinates. D. F. Schloss gave the example of the London Stevedores where — **If a foreman does not give all the men a fairly equal chance of employment, the trade union committee may punish him by suspension. ' * The Brass Workers have a definite rule for con- trolling their foreman members ; — "A member who is a journeyman, foreman, charge- hand or piece worker [i.e. subcontractor] shall not have under his control or supervision or employ any person above the age of 18 who is not a member of the society, and to whom he does not pay the minimum rate of the district. ' ' A thousand Glasgow Dockers struck in 1911 on the demand that a foreman should join the union, and carried their point. Sub-foremen are in- cluded in the compulsory unionism agreements of the Dyers, and, in a number of unions — no- tably the Dyers and Miners — it is not uncommon for foremen and even a few managers to belong to the men's union. In this case the object — where there has been a conscious object — has been to ''capture" the fore- men for quite immediate purposes. Those who are propagandists for extensions of workers ' con- THE ORGANIZATION OF FOREMEN 129 trol are much more strongly in favor of the in- clusion of foremen within the unions as a step towards full trade union management of industry. A correspondent writing to the Amalgamated Society of Engineers Journal puts their argu- ment vigorously: — "On this point [amalgamation with the other en- gineering unions and the control of the industry] we are all so cordially unanimous that there seems nothing left to do in the matter except amalgamate and take con- trol. May I suggest that we have a long row to hoe yet, and that we members of the A.S.E. have not yet done all we might to strengthen our own organization. . . . Any member of our society who, because of his ability, is entrusted with a position of responsibility, is no longer to be helped by the A.S.E. . . . The foremen are being induced by employers to join subsidized mutual organizations of one kind or another in order to set them as a class apart from the ordinary working trade unionist. Some of them still realize that they are workers in the best sense of the word and have interests in common with other producers. ... I would suggest. Sir, that it is of the utmost importance that we should in any measure of control of industry, have the active support of foremen and staff men generally." The various lines of policy taken by employers on this question have also some bearing on the question of control. An early policy was simply that of forbidding membership in trade unions. This was the attitude of the railway companies 130 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL in 1907, before the great increase in railway unionism. It is clearly expressed in the memo- randum from one of the companies to a certain Inspector Rawlinson, transferring him to another position without loss of pay: — "As a member of the Amalgamated Society of Rail- way Servants, you cease to be a free agent, and you can- not be permitted to have the control and supervision of men who are not members of the society or members of some other society. You cannot serve two masters. There is no desire to punish you, but the Company's staff and the Company's business must be protected." Even in 1911, a high official of one of the roads, testifying before a government coromission, threatened that ''non-unionists would have to be chosen" for the work of some of the supervisory clerks which was "more or less of a confidential nature." Less drastic expressions of this feeling are the agreements secured by the employers to the effect that, ''The National Association of Operative Plasterers will not take any steps to compel men regularly employed as foremen or superintendents to become members of the N. A. 0. P. ; " and, in bookbinding, that the Society will not call out on strike a foreman who has held his position for twelve months. Another policy of certain employers has been to encourage separate unions for foremen and other THE ORGANIZATION OP FOREMEN 131 isupervisors by way of keeping them out of the more dangerous trade unions. This may mean, as it does in the engineering and heavy steel trades, a Foremen's Benefit Society, heavily sub- sidized by the employers, which the foremen are urged or compelled to join. One object of this is explained by the Vice-President of the Joint Institute of Engineers, Mr. Alex. Richardson, in The Mem-Power of the Nation (p. 77) : — "So long as foremen continued trade unionists, they could not exhibit independence, and the employers there- fore acted wisely in establishing foremen's societies, which conferred on members the superannuation and other benefits they had to forfeit upon severing their connection with the trade unions. That was a move in the direction of inculcating habits of thought different from those of the ordinary workmen. ' ' The same attitude may mean less definite forms of encouragement to a separate union. The Pot- tery Officials' and Managers' Union came about in this way: — The operatives' society had organ- ized a section of under-managers and foremen, had secured a war bonus for them, and had fought a reinstatement case for one of its manager-mem- bers. The employers then announced that they would be glad to recognize a separate officials' union, and the foremen — with the exception of those in the firm affected by the reinstatement 132 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL strike — left the workers' society and joined the new union. The two unions are now friendly enough; but in the Joint Industrial Council the foremen's union has just been granted two seats, not on the workers' side, as has been suggested in certain other industries, not on an independ- ent ''cross bench," as they had asked, but on the employers' side. The history of these two policies on the part of employers was condensed in the deliberations of the Provisional Joint Committee of the Na- tional Industrial Conference, which reported on April 4, 1919. The question of foremen came up as an obstacle to agreement on ''full and frank" recognition of trade unions as the basis of negotiation. The first proposal of the em- ployers was that workers "in positions of trust or confidentiality" should be definitely excluded in the recommendation for recognition of unions. Their second proposal was that separate unions of foremen, secretaries, etc. should be recognized but that the right of ordinary trade unions "to speak and act on behalf of" their foremen mem- bers 'Should not be conceded. The Committee nearly failed to reach unanimity but finally agreed on the following formula: — "The machinery [for settling disputes] should also contain provisions for the protection of the employers' THE ORGANIZATION OF FOREMEN 133 interests where members of trade unions of work people are engaged in positions of trust or confidentiality, pro- vided the right of such employers to join or remain mem- bers of any trade union is not thereby affected." It is, of course, by no means true that sepa- rate unions of supervisors are always or neces- sarily hostile to the other trade unions. The Na- tional Foremen's Society, recently formed in the engineering and allied trades in opposition to the Foremen's Benefit Society, claimed in July, 1919 a membership of 2,000. Its policy is definitely trade union and includes the obligation not to do ''blackleg" work in case of strikes by the men working under its members. The South Wales Colliery Officials' Union is affiliated to the South Wales Miners' Federation,^ although in many districts there has been considerable friction be- tween the Miners ' Federation and separate organ- izations of Under-managers, Deputies, or Master Hauliers. The Federation of Weavers * and Over- lookers ' ^ Amalgamations in the cotton industry- has already been mentioned as a genuine labor alliance. In this case there is an unusual form of control over supervision; if a woman weaver complains of a bullying overlooker, the matter is • Coal Commission Evidence. Question 18192. • The overlookers in the textile industries are not strictly com- parable to foremen in other industries. They are primarily me- chanics and only incidentally supervisors. 134 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL adjusted between the two unions concerned. The Power Loom Overlookers are represented on the workers' side of the Joint Industrial Council in the woolen trades, and a London Union of Clerical Workers and Builders' Foremen has applied for representation with the workers in the Building Trades Parliament. The largest of all unions of supervisors and clerical workers, the Railway Clerks ' Association, which is rapidly extending its organization into the higher grades * works as an ally of the National Union of Eailwaymen and has been conspicuous in demanding workers' control. The organization of foremen, then, involves in some cases an indirect but genuine control by the workers over the conduct of their supervisors. Its extension is clearly in the policy of certain groups of workers who are consciously aiming at control. And certain employers have attempted either to prevent the process of organization or to divert it into separate and exclusive channels in the fear of just that sort of control. * By a recent agreement between the R. C. A. and the Com- panies there are now only some two hundred of the higher rail- way olBcials in the country who are held to be ineligible to be members of and be represented by the railway unions. THE STANDARD OF FOREMANSHIP WoRKEKs' choice of foremen is rare; the effect of organization of foremen on workers' control is real but indirect. The most important means by which workers exercise control over their super- visors is simply that of the strike or threat of strike when supervision becomes unbearable. The effective power of this form of control is usually underestimated since it is difficult to detect and define and can hardly be embodied in a formal agreement. But in proportion to the strength of the trade union, it represents a real veto, if not actually over the choice, at least over the re- tention of foremen — and a real regulation of their actions. Mr. R. H. Tawney sums up the situation as "autocracy checked by insurgence;" the present point is that there is a great deal of insurgence. Some sense of this may be gained by going through the official Reports on Strikes and Lock- outs.^ In 1912 there were thirty-two disputes re- ported as caused by objections to certain foremen ; in 1913, 25 disputes involving 10,500 workers. * See Note on Sources. 135 136 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL The reports of causes read like these: — '* al- leged harassing conduct of a foreman," "alleged tyrannical conduct of an under-forewoman,'* ** alleged overbearing conduct of officials." The award in a recent arbitration case details the charges against an unpopular under-manager as ** indifference to and want of consideration of suggestions made to him by workers in connec- tion with their work and improvements; uncivil, inconsiderate, harsh and autocratic treatment, and neglect to properly consider their claims as regards both employment and remuneration; and the preference of friends and relatives." And among the results of the strikes, along with numer- ous dismissals and resignations of the officials in question, there are occasional agreements that, * ' the men must be treated with proper respect and threats and abusive language must not be used," or ''tyrannical acts to cease." The number and the frequent success of these strikes indicates, as was suggested in Section VIII, a considerable trade union veto over the choice of foremen. The ' ' right of rejecting as fel- low-workers" may often become the right of re- jecting as foremen. This alone, however, does not sufficiently emphasize the amount of trade union pressure effective in setting a standard of decent foremanship. The rules of the British Steel Smelters provide that members leaving on ac- THE STANDARD OF FOREMANSHIP 137 count of "unjustifiable abuse or ill-treatment from employer or foreman ' ' are entitled to dispute pay. The . secretary of a union which had never suc- ceeded in securing the dismissal of a bullying fore- man was nevertheless sure that its protests were effective as warnings to foremen. And in some trades a definite standard is so much a matter of course that the issue rarely arises. The Com- positors, for example, will not stand for what is known as ''policing" by foremen and managers and any violation of the code is immediately re- ported to the union for action. A story was told me by a former miners' agent in Lanarkshire illustrating a similar standard on the part of the Scottish Miners. In a case arising under the Minimum Wage Act, the overman was called upon to testify whether or not a certain workman did his work properly. The examination was as fol- lows (in free translation from the original Scotch) : — Overman: "I never saw him work." Magistrate: "But isn't it your duty under the Mines Act to visit each working place twice a day?" "Yes." "Don't you do it?" "Yes." "Then why didn't you ever see him work?" "They always stop work when they see an overman coming, and sit down and wait till he's gone — even take 188 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL out their pip^ if it's a mine free from gas. They won't let anybody watch them." An equally extreme standard was enforced for a part of the war period at a Clyde engineering works. The convenor (chairman) of shop stewards was told one morning that there was a grievance at the smithy. He found one of the blacksmiths in a rage because the managing di- rector, in his ordinary morning's walk through the works, had stopped for five minutes or so and watched this man's fire. After a shop meeting the convenor took up a deputation to the director and secured the promise that it should not happen again. At the next works meeting the convenor reported the incident to the body of workers — with the result that a similar standard came into effect throughout the works, and the director hardly dared stop at all on his morning's walk. Much of the feeling in struggles for the recog- nition of unions (long since secured in the better- organized trades and conceded in principle at least for all by the unanimous recommendations of the National Industrial Conference) was due to the workers' desire to have someone outside the control of the immediate employer to represent them on just these questions. This finds very definite expression in the dispute that occasionally arises over the trade union ofiicial's claim of the THE STANDARD OF FOREMANSHIP 139 right to enter the works in order to investigate disputes. This has been paralleled during the war by the frequent claim of the shop steward or of the covenor (chairman) of shop stewards or of the chairman of the Works' Committee for free- dom to go into any department of the works to investigate a grievance. An amusing story was told me of the way this right was won in one of the Clyde ship-building works: — The convenor had begun to exercise the right — and to go freely from shop to shop as disputes arose — without the permission of the management. The manager then ordered him to stop and to stay at his own machine. The convenor obeyed, but ar- ranged for a grievance to occur the next morn- ing in the shop farthest from his own. The steward from that shop came to him with word of the grievance. **I can't leave my work." — *'But it's important." — **How many men in- volved?"— ''200."—** I don't dare leave my ma- chine. Tell them to come to me. " And so the 200 men walked the length of the works, gathered round the convenor's machine while he kept on with his work, and discussed the dispute. The re- sult— in the prevailing shortage of labor — was the concession of the privilege. But the fighting of the same issue in another works, with Mr. David Kirkwood as the shop steward in question, led to the deportation of the Clyde strike leaders in 1916. 140 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL The shop stewards' agreement of December, 1917, between the engineering employers and certain of the engineering unions provided that: — "In connection with this agreement shop stewards shall be afforded facilities to deal with questions raised in the shop or portion of a shop in which they are em- ployed. In course of dealing with these questions they may, with the previous consent of the management (such consent not to be unreasonably withheld) , visit any other shop or portion of a shop in the establishment. In all other respects shop stewards shall conform to the same working conditions as their f ellow- workmen. " The Works Committees report of the Ministry of Labor states that, "from the experience of several works ... it would appear that this free- dom of movement is found to be an essential con- dition of the success of a committee." The vari- ous elaborate methods of procedure for the presentation of grievances by trade union officials or shop stewards, whether embodied in long-standing collective agreements or in recent constitutions of works committees (as well as the various provisions for securing for the aggrieved individual the *' principle of the open door" to the higher management) are beside the present point. The interesting thing for our purpose is that they involve a recognition that grievances of this sort are within the field of action of the THE STANDARD OF FOREMANSHIP 141 workers' representatives. An editorial in The Post (the journal of the Postmen's Federation) of March 8, 1918, emphasized as one of the chief functions of the shop steward his duties in *'a case of petty spite or constant bullying from an overseer or a foreman. " ' ^ It would appear, ' ' says the Works Co^nmittees report, *Hhat a Works Committee, if it is to be of any value in ventilat- ing and removing grievances, must be in a position to ventilate grievances arising from the conduct of foremen and overlookers. Such grievances touch the worker most closely in his daily work." The case already referred to at Reuben Gaunt 's, Ltd., in which a foreman charged with bullying was tried by a joint body representing the manage- ment and the workers, is a definite embodiment of this principle. These are still only partial indications of the importance of grievances against foremen in trade union activity. The union may try to secure the discharge of an arbitrary foreman ; the union may secure consideration of its grievances against him by peaceful means. But frequently the resent- ment merely smolders and breaks out on other issues. This feeling, whether or not it appears on the face of the workers' demands, is un- doubtedly, as the secretary of an employers' as- sociation told me, "at the bottom of some of the bitterest strikes." A correspondent writing to 142 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL the Times during the railway dispute of 1907 declared that: — "The whole cause of these continued disturbances is due to the authority and petty tyranny exercised by the foremen, who are nothing less than despots and slave-drivers. * ' And the Commission on Industrial Unrest in 1917, in analyzing the unrest in South Wales, said:— 1 "We must also recognize the fact that the Welsh collier, even though possibly addicted to bluntness of speech in conversation with his fellow-workmen is quick to resent any ebullition of temper or violence of language towards himself on the part of those placed in authority over him. . . . Much avoidable friction is due to lack of self-control in language and temper and want of tact generally on the part of officials, though circumstances may often be such as to test them severely in this respect. ' * The control exercised by trade unions over the actions of foremen is a real and continuous thing, though it gains public notice only when it is fought for in a strike. It is not of course argued that this control is wholly different from the modicum of control exercised by any body of men under supervision, whether organized or unorganized. The manager who sees that a certain foreman THE STANDARD OF FOREMANSHIP 143 fails to get the best work out of his men because he is unpopular and so replaces him is to that extent "controlled" by the dislikes of the workers. Moreover, any group of men, no matter how help- lessly situated, enforces, if only by nagging and sulkiness, some sort of standard of treatment from its overseers — a standard which I was made to feel very definitely in a few days' service as a prison guard. The most accurate literary ex- pression of this group-standard, in The Code by Robert Frost, is written of the completely unor- ganized ** hired men" of the New England farms : — "The hand that knows his business won't be told To do work faster or better-;-these two things." But from the individual hired man, working alongside the small farmer in the hurry to get in the hay before a rain and defending his **code" by simply thrusting his pitchfork into the ground and marching himself off the field, it is a long way to the action of the whole body of workers in a great engineering establishment or in a group of coal pits scattered up and down a Welsh val- ley, no individual of whom is of any particular importance to the employer, nevertheless enforc- ing by their collective power a certain level of personal treatment when one foreman has vio- lated the code in respect to one worker. No one 144 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL claims that trade unionism is mere knight erran- try, that a high recklessness over obscure and delicate points of honor leads to lack of caution in regard to trade union funds or the interests of trade union members. Even the authors of the Miners' Next Step, for all their insistence on fight- ing individual grievances that involve principles, recommend as a point of tactics that : — "Whenever it is contemplated bringing any body of men out on strike, demands must be put forward to improve the status of each section so brought out." But the extent to which decent foremanship may be felt to be a matter of union and inter-union con- cern is suggested by the description, in the annual report of the Furnishing Trades Association for 1917, of joint action by the metal and woodwork- ing trades in an aircraft factory: — "A mass-meeting of all sections made it quite clear that they were determined to insist that any attempt to treat any group of men without regard to their feelings or self-respect would be treated as a challenge to all the unions, and as such would be taken up and replied to by a general stoppage of work. They demand the right to work under a manager who will treat them as men inside the shop." A standard of foremanship, or at least a stand- ard of manners in foremen, enforced in the more THE STANDARD OF FOREMANSHIP 145 spectacular cases by striking for the foreman's dismissal but also by other methods of steady pressure, is as real — though less definite and pos- sibly less universal — a subject of trade union regu- lation as the standard of wages itself. XI SPECIAL MANAGERIAL FUNCTIONS The last three sections dealt with the relation of labor to its supervisors. This section deals with the relation of labor to certain special functions of supervision, usually thought of as the business of foremen or managers but sometimes exercised by the workers. The first of these is the enforcement of minor discipline. There is, as the Ministry of Labor reports, **a considerable body of experience" of the exercise of disciplinary functions by works committees. The experience to which that report refers falls, however, entirely into two classes, — oases of administering bonus schemes under which deductions are made for various offences, and cases of enforcing special war-time discip- line under the power or the threat of the Muni- tions of War Act. In a typical instance of the first, a joint committee meets monthly to assess the fines incurred for the following offences : — "a. Insubordination, or use of improper language. b. Undue carelessness and wilful damage, e. Neglect to enter goods, advices, time cards, dockets or time sheets." 146 SPECIAL MANAGERIAL FUNCTIONS 147 The war emergency cases are more interesting. The Munitions of War Act of 1915 and the regula- tions issued under its authority by the Ministry of Munitions put discipline in the *' controlled establishments " ^ on a basis totally different from peace conditions. Violations of a firm's posted rules were subject to prosecution in special courts, the munitions tribunals, in which a chairman ap- pointed by the Ministry acted as judge with an equal number of assessors representing the em- ployers and the trade unions. This method was in many cases felt by both parties to be a nuisance, and various experiments in joint discipline were tried. The Whitehead Torpedo Works, in sug- gesting a joint scheme to its employees, said: — "There is a class of rules, offences against which are punishable by a fine of half a crown dismissal, or a prosecution under the Munitions Act. None of these penalties is a convenient one. Fines are as much dis- liked by the firm as by the men ; dismissal entails the loss of services which may be badly needed; and prosecu- tions entail great waste of time and may produce more evils than the original ones they are meant to cure. ' ' * " If the Minister of Munitions considers it expedient for the fmrpose of the successful prosecution of the war that any estab- ishment in which munition work is carried on should be subject to the special provisions as to limitation of employers' profits and control of persons employed and other matters contained in this section, he may make an order declaring that establishment to be a controlled establishment." Munitions of War Act, 1915, Part II, Section 4. 148 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL Some committees were reluctant to take on themselves the responsibility and unpopularity of punishing their fellows; those that accepted it probably did so with the feeling that the special war powers of the employer made punishment inevitable and that this was a way of making it reasonable. In one remarkable case a Works Tribunal — not a joint committee but a chairman and a jury of twelve elected wholly by the work- ers— exercised authority over these matters and is said to have brought about great improvement in discipline and timekeeping. "Bad timekeeping," by the way — i.e. irregular attendance at work — wa's the most important of- fence which came under this sort of discipline. Special joint committees to deal with this prob- lem were set up at the suggestion of the Ministry of Munitions in the ironworks of Cleveland and Durham. The duties and powers of the local committees were defined as follows in the Cleve- land rules: — " (a) To inquire fully into every ease brought by the Manager of the Works of alleged bad timekeeping on the part of any workman employed at the works under his charge. (b) To give warning and advice to any workman who may appear to need it. (c) To inflict subject to the provisions of the Truck Acts, such penalty or fine as in the judgment of the Com- SPECIAL MANAGERIAL FUNCTIONS 149 mittee the case shall merit, such fine not to exceed twenty shillings in any one instance. (d) In the case of repeated offences, to transmit the facts and evidence to the judgment of the Cen- tral. (e) In the event of the Works Committee being equally divided on any case [wliich, it may be added, is said to have happened very rarely] the same shall be submitted to the Central Committee for decision. (f) Each Works Committee shall have power to re- duce or remit altogether any fine imposed by the Com- mittee, if the offender's conduct during the four weeks succeeding the hearing of his case justifies any variation in the original penalty." All these cases were under the direct power of the Munitions of War Act, and accepted only for its duration. The only further extension of this principle was in the Absentee Committees of the Miners, which in their development as Output Committees were one of the most interesting by- products of the war and will be discussed in a later chapter. Much the same argument, however, was used while the Miners were discussing the question of assuming responsibility for the at- tendance of their members. **If we don't accept it, we may be put under the Act. Then there'll be punishment anyway; we had better see that it's done justly." The ** appeal to all mine workers" for good timekeeping, issued as a plac- ard by the Yorkshire Miners, read in part: — 150 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL "Fellow Workers: This appeal is made to prevent more drastic measures being brought to bear upon our great industry by the Government." "It is a line of punishment by your own men," said one of the Miners' leaders, ''and if the men have no confidence in their own men who have been selected from their own branch, whom can they have confidence in?" A second of these special managerial functions is that of providing for the safety of the workers. Here it is naturally the Miners that have needed and secured the greatest extent of control. The Mines Acts of 1911 and earlier give the workers power to appoint an inspector of their own to make a complete examination of the machinery and workings as often as once a month and also to make examination, in company with a legal ad- viser or with a mining or electrical engineer, after an accident. How much this privilege means in practice is hard to estimate, and probably varies greatly from district to district. A correspon- dent writing to the Colliery Engmeman claims that it means very little in Cumberland : — "The Act which enables mine- workers to appoint a person to periodically inspect every part of the mine, ventilating apparatus, machinery, etc., has been allowed to remain a dead letter at most of the collieries in this SPECIAL MANAGERIAL FUNCTIONS 151 coalfield. One of the chief reasons for this has been that if the persons elected as local inspectors give an adverse report, the management would soon find some means of getting rid of them. ... It is not uncommon to be told by mine-workers that their mine has not been examined by local inspectors for 10 years. During the inquiry into the Senyhenyd explosion, 1911, in which 439 men and boys lost their lives it came out in evi- dence that the miners had not inspected the mine for 18 months. The reason the men gave was that no man dared to give a true report." On the other hand a South Wales leader declared that : — "In many parts of the South Wales coalfield, the workmen themselves have appointed practical exam- iners, and these men are doing very excellent work, in my opinion, preventing accidents." but advocated that these examiners be empowered to prosecute the owners for violations. Even as the law stands, however, it implies a definite statutory recognition of the right of the workers to take an active and independent part in the prevention of accident. The Miners' Federation also claims responsi- bility for the clauses in the Mines Act which set the qualifications of the firemen, examiners, and deputies — the officials directly entrusted with safety functions. Here again the miners claim that these men have not dared to report faithfully 152 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL the conditions for fear of the employers. At their 1917 Conference, the Miners' Federation passed the following resolution in order, as they claimed, to secure for the men in these positions a combi- nation of the fearlessness of the government in- spector and the knowledge of the practical miner:— "That it would be conducive to the best interests of the miners that firemen, examiners, and deputies should be appointed by the workmen and paid by the State." The report of the Commission on Industrial Un- rest in South Wales (1917) recommended that the appointment and dismissal of those officials should be entrusted to joint committees. Certain of the Deputies' Associations favored the oppo- site— state control and appointment — in order to secure freedom from pressure from either side. The Miners have also exerted a considerable negative control over safety arrangements by re- fusing to work under conditions they thought dangerous. There are a number of references to these "safety strikes" scattered through the evi- dence before the Coal Commission. One of the more specific occurs in the testimony of Mr. Win- stone of the South Wales Miners' Federation: — **Q. Was there a stoppage in Monmouthshire re- cently ? A. Yes. SPECIAL MANAGERIAL FUNCTIONS 153 Q. Do you mind telling us the nature of the stoppage! A. The stoppage took place at the Risca Colliery in. Monmouthshire where 15,000 men were idle for several days owing to a danger arising from gas, a shortage of timber, and the dukie rope cutting into the timber and cutting through the rails. Q. That is what we could call a safety strike? A. Yes. Then at the Bedwas Mine the men are out today because of a safety stoppage. The owners de- clined to stall the place, and the men were fearing that a crush would take place, and so they stopped." These disputes are not only interesting as in- dicating a degree of present control but as often furnishing the background for further demands for control. A miner who had been discharged from a Scotch colliery for refusing to work in a place which he considered dangerous explained his case in great detail and with diagrams in a leaflet addressed to his fellow-workers at the colliery and reprinted in The Worker (Glasgow) of September 27, 1919. The moral which he drew was this : — "If I lost, it's you who have lost, for you will have lost the right to decide yourselves about the safety of your own place. My idea is that we should demand that chocks — hard wood chocks — should be put in every loosened place and kept up with the face. That as soon as possible we should appoint pit committees to con- trol the method of working; this would guarantee more safety to the coal getter." 154 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL The same feeling was expressed as a part of the official policy of the Miners' Federation by Mr. Robert Smillie in the course of a deputation to the Prime Minister, on October 9, 1919, to de- mand nationalization and joint control: — * * The miners put forward their claim primarily on the question of safety." The Miners, then, have considerable power, both legal and actual, over the safety of the mines and are pressing vigorously for further control. There is in the other industries no case of workers* con- trol over safety to compare with this. It is true that in many industries there are Factory Act reg- ulations— often secured in part by trade union agi- tation— and even occasional provisions for inspec- tors appointed by workpeople ; but in practice they apparently involve little or no trade union action. There is, however, at least one interesting case of the beginnings of joint control. A joint sub- committee of the Builders ' Parliament in conjunc- tion with representatives from the Whitley Coun- cils in the other wood-working industries and in consultation with the manufacturers of wood- working machines, has made a study of the dan- gers arising from the use of wood-working ma- chinery. Its report of August 14, 1919, contains a series of detailed suggestions intended as a basis for further regulations under the Factory Acts. SPECIAL MANAGERIAL FUNCTIONS 155 A third and less important special function of supervision occasionally exercised by the workers is that of the allocation of work, i.e. the distribu- tion within a given group of workers of the par- ticular jobs or working places. The question is of some importance in many piece-work trades, and there is much complaint among the miners and others that favoritism in assigning working-places and jobs is used as a covert method of victimiza- tion. There are very few cases, however, in which complaint has gone over into control. Lord Gain- ford, the chief representative of the coal-owners, told the Coal Commission of the system in effect in the Durham coalfield : — "In our county at the end of every quarter the men ballot amongst themselves for the different positions in the mines. The men as a rule are allowed to select their own working mates, and they go into the place which has been selected by ballot." The printers furnish the best example of control under this head; a ''companionship" (team) of compositors on piece work has the right to appoint its own ''clicker" who distributes the work so as to divide equitably "the fat" {i.e. work on which good money can be made) . It is probable that in many trades there are occasional instances of in- formal control of this sort, as, for example, at a certain "pot-bank" in which the equalization of 156 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL work between one team (of jiggerer, turner, and handler) and another is arranged by the men. A writer in the Railway Review suggests that ** allo- cations of turns of duty" are a field for joint or workers' control to replace what he calls the "in- competency and want of foresight and arrange- ment on the part of petty ofl&cials, ' ' and suggests that '*at each depot ... a representative of the men might be periodically chosen to regulate these turns of duty. " The issue is even more important in the case of the street railways, where the real irksomeness of the working day depends not so much on the number of hours actually worked as on the ** spread-over time" between the beginning of the first run and the end of the last. The mat- ter depends almost solely upon the care spent in arranging the working schedules, and the tram- waymen in Leeds and other parts of Yorkshire have recently won a substantial concession in securing the right to be consulted in any change of these schedules — a right which at the time of the last change amounted in substance to the actual working-out of the schedules by the union ofiicials and a large increase in the percentage of con- tinuous runs. The fourth of these special functions of manage- ment is that of the measurement of results. There are instances of a degree of control by SPECIAL MANAGERIAL FUNCTIONS 157 workers over the two matters of measurement of quantity (where the pay is based on the amount of output of the individual or the works), and measurement of quality (where deductions are made from the pay for spoiled work). The best known and longest established case under the first head is that of the miners ' checkweighman. By a law of 1887 (which strengthened a law of 1860) a majority of miners in each pit may appoint a representative to watch the weighing of the coal at the pit's mouth and to keep an accurate check on the recording of each man's work, and the checkweighman 's pay is deducted from the wages of all the coal-getters who are paid by weight. A strike of 120O men in 1913 ''against raising and tipping coal after the fixed hour and in absence of checkweighman," is an indication that this right is felt to be an important one ; the incidental result of the arrangement, in providing a means of support for Miners' Federation officials, has been exultantly pointed out by the Webbs and others. A bill extending this practice to certain other industries, — iron and steel works, the docks, limestone and chalk quarries, etc. — ^was intro- duced by the Labor Party and passed by the pres- ent Parliament. This is a case of the right to safeguard the earnings of the individual piece worker. A slightly different situation is that in which the payment depends, not on the output of 158 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL the individual, but on that of the works. In the Durham coke-ovens the pay is based on the aver- age weight of coke produced by the ovens. The agreement in regard to the "Ascertainment of Yield" is as follows: — "That for the purpose of correctly ascertaining the average weight of coke produced per oven at any yard either party may require that the coke be weighed . . . the men to have the liberty to send a man to inspect and take a copy of the weighings of coke as recorded in the weighman's book." A check on the judgment of quality is important in a few of the smaller trades, in which deductions are made for spoiled and bad work, though it is obviously a more difficult matter for joint or trade union action than a simple weighing of tons of coal. In pottery the custom of paying only for ware that comes "good from oven" and the lack of any joint means of assessing the fault in cases of breakage is at present a subject of dispute. In nut and bolt making, there is the rough and ready check of putting all rejected work on the scrap heap in the presence of its maker. The value is assessed and agreed upon and deducted from the maker's earnings; the waste is then his property. The elaborate regulations of the Yorkshire Glass Bottle Makers for determining the responsibility for bad work are worth quoting, if only as in- dicating the old-fashioned nature of the trade: — SPECIAL MANAGERIAL FUNCTIONS 159 "That bottles picked out [rejected] be not broken down until the men have had an opportunity of inspect- ing them In all cases of bad or faulty metal the men shall immediately send for the manager to take the responsibility. . . . Any workman commencing to work knowing the metal to be bad, without skimming it according to the established custom of the trade, or fail- ing to carry out the conditions herein specified, shall not be entitled to payment for the bottles put out." The Nottingham lace weavers put the deter- mination of the fault entirely in the hands of the shop committee: — "No stoppage [deduction] shall be made for places caused by the fault of the machine. . . . Where neglect of the workman causes extra mending, places across or spoiled work, and where a workman fails to carry out written instructions in a workmanlike manner a claim for stoppage may be made by the employer, but all claims must be supplied in writing with particulars to the shop committee. Unless the shop committee re- ceive such particulars and consent to the stoppage, no stoppage shall be made and the employer shall be left to such other remedy as may be open to him." The sum of duties exercised by the representa- tives of the workers under these special manager- ial functions is considerable. THeir importance in a study of control is lessened by two facts: — the most highly-developed cases of the enforcement of discipline were definitely for the war emergency 160 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL in fear of worse things, and do not at all represent the responsibilities the greater number of trade unionists are ready to accept under peace con- ditions ; the control under the other heads is almost entirely a mere check on the care or honesty of the employer and involves little independent direction. The exercise of the disciplinary function was then mainly an emergency measure ; the other functions might be more accurately spoken of as check- managerial than managerial. xn METHODS OF PAYMENT The last section clearly raises the question of the methods of payment of wages. The issue of the amount of wages falls outside our definition; the issue of the method of payment, however *'im- mediate to the wage bargain itself, ' ' is too closely bound up with the methods of control to be com- pletely passed by. There is certainly no use in attempting to go over all the ground covered by Mr. D. F. Schloss's Methods of Industrial Re- mimeration (1892, 1894 and 1898) or Mr. G. D. H. Cole's Payment of Wages (1918). The object is merely to show how the arguments for and against certain methods of payment are colored by the struggle for control, and how various methods of payment have given rise to particular attempts at workers' control. The first point is suggested by a comparison of the two books mentioned. Mr. Schloss declared that : — "In regard to the method of industrial remuneration Trade Unionism does not propose to make any change whatever in the arrangements now prevailing." 161 162 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL The more recent movements grouped as the ''Demand for Control" make such a statement no longer possible. Mr. Cole's book is in fact largely taken up with the arguments for and against various changes which trades unionists (if not Trade Unionism) are anxious either to make or to prevent. It is here worth while merely to mention a few of the issues to indicate the com- plexity of motives and their bearing on "control" as well as on the amount of wages. The various wood-working trades, for example, have been strik- ing or agitating for the abandonment of the piece work and premium bonus systems which had in some cases been forced upon them during the war. Here the issue of quality of workmanship — ^which the workers claim is sacrificed under piece work — seems to be more real than in most trades, though it is by no means the only motive. The Carpenters' and Joiners ' Journal argues : — "That employers who desire the best class of crafts- manship put into any kind of joinery work, never re- quest joiners to adopt premium bonus or piece work sys- tems, because all men — employers and workmen alike — recognize that either of the above named systems in- evitably leads to "rushing" work, therefore necessarily "scamping" work, and consequently the demoralizing effect in the long run hinders instead of assisting in increasing the output of the genuine craftsman's pro- duction. ' ' METHODS OF PAYMENT 163 In engineering and other industries a guerrilla warfare is being waged over the introduction and the conditions of introduction of piece work and more especially of premium bonus and "efficiency'* systems. The general argument of the employers for the introduction of payment by results is that it is necessary as providing an incentive for greater production — a way to ''speed up" the workers. Some of them favor collective payment by results, that is, payment based on the output of the whole shop or works, as a way of getting the workers to ''speed each other up" — which recalls the old argument for profit sharing that it "makes every workman an overseer." The motives of the workers who oppose the system are various — a dis- taste for being speeded up and the past experience and fear of rate-cutting are among the chief. A fairly constant argument against individual piece work in many industries is that it makes collec- tive bargaining harder to enforce and that it di- vides the workers against themselves instead of making for the "solidarity of labor," — that is, as the Ironfotmders' Journal puts it, "That it promotes selfishness in the workshop." On the other hand I heard a printing employer argue on just the same ground against a change to piece- work which his employees wanted — that it would destroy the good team work among his com- positors. The Miners' Federation at its 1917 Con- 164 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL ference passed a resolution in favor of the aboli- tion of piece work; but a vigorous minority in- sisted that time work would mean much more irk- some supervision, that ''you would probably want a doggy or a deputy in every stall to see that the men are working their hardest." Somewhat the same point is occasionally put in the statement that the workers "feel freer" in regard to attend- ance under piece work. The most conspicuous ad- vocates of workers' control, including Mr. Frank Hodges of the Miners and Mr. Gr. D. H. Cole, are in favor of time work.^ With that opinion, as it applies to future policy, it is not the affair of the present study to deal ; from the historical point of view,^ one fact might be set on the other side, that the genuine interest of the miners in the problems of mine-management, as well as the favorable attitude of the cotton operatives toward improvements in machinery, are partly traceable to their piece-work systems. In any case, it is clear that the quarrels over methods of payment cannot be completely disentangled from the gen- eral question of the control of industry. For the present purpose, however, it is more useful to examine the specific forms of control developed or advocated in connection with the methods of payment now in force. Most of the * The qualifications which Cole would attach to this opinion are stated on pp. Ill and 112 of The Payment of Wages. METHODS OF PAYMENT 166 labor arguments for time work are negative, that is, arguments that piece work is more dangerous to the standard rate; therefore it is no surprise to find fewer special forms of control under pay- ment by time. The only case I know of, in fact, of the exercise by workers of unusual functions of direction under any sort of time system, is that of the ''grading system" of the Birmingham brass trades. There the executive of the National Union of Brass Workers grades each worker according to his ability and places him in one of seven differ- ent classes, for each of which a minimum wage is set by collective bargaining. If an employer chal- lenges the qualifications of any man, a practical examination in the processes of the trade is given him by the managers of the Municipal Brass Trades School. Piece work and the more complicated systems of payment by results naturally show more in- stances of union activity, if not a greater degree of control, over the methods of payment. The difference of course lies, not in the bargaining for the general standard of wages, but in the ap- plication of the standard rate to the setting of par- ticular piece rates (or, under bonus systems, basic times) for particular jobs or processes. The pro- cedure varies much more widely than can be in- dicated here, but may be thought of as falling into two broad classes, — that in which ''lists'* or agree- 166 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL ments reached by formal collective bargaining cover every process in the trade, and that in which the setting of the particular price is more or less entirely a matter between the employer and the individual workman or immediate groups of work- men concerned. The outstanding example of the first class is the cotton industry, where the ex- pert secretaries of the two associations, with no motive for setting a new price in a single mill either above or below the general standard of Lancashire and with a strong professional pride in the correctness of their mathematics, have little diflficulty in applying the elaborate agreed lists to any variation of speed, pattern, or process. Their greatest difficulty (aside of course from the gen- eral level of wages), has been the ''bad spinning" question, i.e. disputes arising from the claims of workers that the cotton supplied them was of such bad quality that they could not make the standard rate at list prices. The Brooklands Agreement, which was the chief treaty governing the industry, broke down in 1912 over just this point, the em- ployers being willing to admit that grievances under this head should be promptly discussed, but refusing to accept a formal agreed test. The same issue occasionally occurs in other industries; in a branch of the woolen trades, it is settled by the following arrangements : — METHODS OF PAYMENT 167 "Should any dispute arise as to the quality of the wool, a sample shall be submitted to the Bradford Con- ditioning House by a representative of the workmen. Each body to abide by the decision of the certificate, and the expenses of the test to be paid by the party found to be in error." A somewhat parallel difficulty is encountered in coal-mining in settling rates for ''abnormal places" — working places that are for one reason or another so difficult that a standard wage can- not be earned without special allowance. The Miners' Minimum Wage Act of 1912 was in part intended to meet this problem by assuring each man a wage irrespective of his place; but, since the minimum rates are in all cases well below the normal earnings in a good place, the question still often leads to serious disputes. These are usually fought out between the miners' agents and the employer and involve no special forms of control. One South Wales colliery, however, works on the agreement that: — "When any variation in the conditions of any work- ing place or places occurs, the person or persons work- ing in such places shall have the right to call in the aid of any two members of the Workmen's Committee, to- gether with two Officers of the Company, in order to agree upon any additional rate or allowance for work- ing such place or places. ' * 168 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL The Commission on Industrial Unrest in its re- port on South Wales recommended, as a subject for discussion in a possible Joint Industrial Council, ''the right of the men with the employers to select an equal number of the workers engaged in carrying out tests in new seams before price lists are arranged." Bate-fixing in the other class of industries, those not covered by lists, may mean anything from purely ''take-it-or-leave-it" determination (whether arbitrary or ''scientific") by the em- ployer or a strictly individual bargain to fairly complete though informal collective bargaining. Engineering is the storm center among this second class of industries and shows the widest variations. The principle which is supposed to govern it is that of "mutuality": — "The prices to be paid shall be fixed by irmtual ar- rangement between the employer and workman or work- men who perform the work. ' ' This means at least a bargain; the worker has the right — which may or may not mean the op- portunity—to say no; as it stands, it may mean no more than individual bargaining. Doubtless, however, there are always the rudiments of a col- lective bargain. One man's acceptance of a bad bargain is obviously the other men's loss, and the METHODS OF PAYMENT . 169 men doubtless talk over their rates. From this informal understanding there are various stages to full collective bargaining. Certain unions make regulations that their men shall not accept rates below those set ''by a majority of members work- ing in the shops." This pricing by shopmates leads naturally to the election of a shop steward or a shop committee to take over the pricing func- tion, a step of great importance as the origin of many of the most active shop committees. This may mean within the shops almost as complete a standardization as in the price-list industries, par- ticularly if the steward or the committee keeps a ''book of prices" with which to compare any new prices offered. The situation is somewhat different in those piece-work and premium bonus systems in which the management employs a special scientific rate- fixer or where the time a job should take is deter- mined in a special time-study office, though a sim- ilar range of variations in procedure occurs here. The whole method may be considered merely the firm's business, or the firm may be willing to dis- cuss with a committee the methods by which prices are fixed but not the prices fixed in individual cases. On the other hand it is quite possible for scientific price fixing to co-exist with a consider- able extent of joint control. On just this point it is worth while to quote at length from the scheme 170 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL and experience of the Phoenix Dynamo Company of Bradford : — "One of the greatest objections to present piece-work systems is that the employer works out the price in secret, writes down the time on a card, and this settles the price. Now, the men feel that payment by results is a bargain and that it is not within the province of the employer to state arbitrarily what the price is to be. . . . On getting out a new job we would calculate the feeds and speeds which were suitable for the tool on which the job was to be performed, and then put forward the time we offer ; you are not bound to accept it and can appeal if you like. In this event you go to the Time Study Office, where the man who has dealt with the job will go through the detail of his calculations, and if he has made a slip will at once put it right. Our time fixing is not infallible, and the men can help us by pointing out errors. If, however, we are unconvinced that the price is unreasonable, and the man is equally unconvinced that it is reasonable, he can then say, *I want this job to go to Committee'. . . . The Committee consists of 3 of the firm's representa- tives and 3 workmen's representatives consisting of the man concerned and 2 workmen selected by him who are operating the same type of machine or whose work is closely allied to the work in question. ... In the event of the Committee failing to agree it is then up to the firm to demonstrate in their own works that the time is fair and that time and a quarter [over the guaran- teed time rate] can be made on it. . . . The surprising part of the scheme over the period METHODS OF PAYMENT 171 in which it has now been operating is the very small number of Committees which are held. It would appear that a very stupid workman who goes to the Time Study Office to argue with the rate-fixer, or a very thick-headed rate-fixer, are either of them rather afraid of what a Committee would decide about their particular case, and so whichever party feels himself to be technically weak- est in the argument appears to give way. ' ' A similar arrangement applies by agreement in the engineering trade at Barrow. This is prob- ably the furthest extent of joint control possible where the specialized skill is still entirely the prop- erty of one side. The Works Committee's pam- phlet already quoted reports the suggestion from a firm's rate-fixer that a desirable next step would be the appointment by the men of a separate rate- fixer of their own — an idea already in opera- tion at a Bristol engineering works in which the firm pays a rate-fixer who is chosen by the men. All these are cases of individual payment by results. But collective payment by results — where the payment is based on the production of a group or team of workers, or on that of the shop or entire factory — has also its direct and important bearings on the problem of control. The connec- tion between collective piece work and control in the smaller crafts has already been mentioned. Perhaps it is worth while to quote again the rep- 172 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL resentative of the Stuff Pressers to illustrate the type:— "This principle of collective payment throws the re- sponsibility upon every individual to contribute his maximum quota to the whole. It has almost completely crushed out of existence the practice of *ca-canny,' for where is the man of sufficient courage to exercise his genius for shirking when the consequences of his action would be to bring down on his head the wrath of the shop?" At the present time workers in engineering and other industries show a much greater readiness to accept collective piece work or a collective (shop or works) bonus on output than the individual systems. Nor can the reason be put quite as sim- ply as by the director of a steel works who told me that the reason for this preference was that **it didn't show up the rotters as quickly." An- other side is put in the resolution in favor of col- lective piece work passed by the Weymouth Joint Committee of Allied Engineering Trades on the ground that, "it restores the old collective spirit, securing collective effort, collective interest and harmony, that it produces evenness of earnings in place of inequality. ' ' An elaborately safeguarded system of collective piece work is that put into force by the Bradford Dyers ' Association in 1913, which contained the following clauses : — METHODS OF PAYMENT 173 "The Association may at any branch introduce pay- ment by piece-work rates. All piece work slmll he based on collective work and collective payment. . . . The fixing of rates and the arrangements of sets shall be mutually agreed upon in writing by representa- tives of the Associations and the Unions. Such rates shall be so fixed as to enable a full rated man to earn not less than 7d. per hour. . . . No rate or set shall he altered witJiout the consent in writing of the Association and the Union or Unions to which the employees {iffected belong. Trials of three calendar months' duration shall pre- cede the final settlement of rates." Under this system the "sets" of workers are said to have taken an increased part in arranging their own work, a development towards control which had been actively in the mind of at least one of the Dyers' leaders who had advocated the scheme. The cases already quoted perhaps cover most of the range of methods of payment which carry with them degrees of workers' control important in the present industrial system. It is worth while, however, to contrast two other systems, which imply much greater control by the workers, co-operative work and collective contract. The former was quoted by D. F. Schloss as an archaic dying system on the very edges of modern indus- try; the latter has been advocated by two Clyde shop stewards as a revolutionary idea for the 174 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL great industry itself. ''The distinctive features of Co-operative Work . . . are that (1) the mem- bers of the co-operative group are associated by their own free choice, determining for themselves of how many persons and of what persons that group shall consist, (2) the associated workmen select from amongst themselves their own leader, and (3) arrange the division of the collective wages between the members of the group in such manner as may be mutually agreed upon between these associates as being' equitable. " ^ Messrs. Gallacher and Paton argue ' that * ' the next step ' ' for a shop stewards' committee, after some ex- perience as the ' * sole medium of contact between the firm and the workers" should be to ''under- take in one large contract, or in two or three con- tracts at most, the entire business of production throughout the establishment. Granted an alli- ance with the organized office-workers — a develop- ment which is assured so soon as the Shop Com- mittees are worthy of confidence and influential enough to give adequate protection — these con- tracts might include the work of design and pur- chase of raw material, as well as the operations of manufacture and construction. But to begin with, the undertaking will cover only the manual operations. The contract price, or wages — for ' D. F. Schloss, op. cit., 1918 edition, p. 155. * Towards Induttrial Democracy. See Note on Sources. METHODS OF PAYMENT 175 it is still wages — will be remitted by the firm to the Works Committee in a lump sum, and dis- tributed to the workers by their own representa- tives, or their officials, and by whatever system or scale of remuneration they choose to adopt. . . . A specially enlightened union of this sort would, no doubt, elect to pool the earnings of its members and pay to each a regular salary weekly, monthly, or quarterly, exacting, of course, from the re- cipient a fixed minimum record of work for the period. . . . The functions of management will have passed to the Committees, and it will be their business to see that contract prices amply cover all the costs of these functions." It is obvious, then, that the various methods of wage payment raise issues far beyond the im- mediate bargaining for wages. Methods of pay- ment themselves depend largely on the technique of the industry concerned, but each system of payment has in turn its by-products in particular forms of attempts at control, and one of the most detailed projects put forward by the propagan- dists for workers ' control is based on a proposed change in the method of payment. But it is high time to discuss the questions raised in the last few sections, not only with reference to the re- lations of man to man in industry, but also more specifically to the relations of man to the tech- nique of production. XIII TECHNIQUE: RESTRICTION AND RESTRICTIONS The people who write about the things the workers do and do not control, often use the broad dis- tinction between conditions of employment on the one hand and methods of production on the other. Sometimes they say that the former are rightly the worker's affair, the latter entirely the em- ployer's. The moral of it is not this book's busi- ness, but the distinction is a help in classifying. The forms of control already studied fall under the first head; those still to be discussed belong to the second. But the division is by no means rigid — the facts do not divide so neatly; no one of the earlier sections has failed to raise questions of the technique of production. Nor does it rep- resent a sharply logical demarcation ; the process at which a man works is perhaps the most im- portant condition of his employment. But clearly in turning to technique, we are coming to a vital part of our subject. We have discussed some of the personal relationships in industry — the politics of industry; but how about the work itself I What 17a RESTRICTION AND RESTRICTIONS 177 control have the organized workers exercised over the actual technology of mdustryf The newspaper reader is likely to think of workers' control over production, if at all, as either sheer restriction of output, or else as a series of restrictions which prevent the use and (where the issue really comes to a head) the in- troduction of the best industrial technique. This section, then, will deal with restriction and re- strictions. Restriction of output — apparently better known as ''this damned restriction of output" — is an interesting subject, if only for the passion it arouses. But it is necessary to examine it very closely to see whether it falls within the range of our inquiry. To decide how much is to be pro- duced— the employer 's decision whether it is more profitable to increase or restrict his output of a certain commodity — is obviously a main element in the control of industry. But it is not claimed that the workers in restricting output (except in one or two rare instances which will be mentioned under ''Trade Policy") have made any conscious attempt to sh^re in that decision. The charge is that the workers — or rather some groups of workers — have been deliberately setting a limit to their own output; deciding for them- selves "what amount of output by each operative should be considered a fair day's work, not to be 178 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL considerably exceeded under penalty of the serious displeasure of the workshop. ' ' There is no doubt at all that a ca'canny (go slow) policy is a serious problem in many industries — rand a ca'canny that cannot bo explained as a mere natural difference between the employer's and the worker's idea of a ''fair day's work." Very likely the extent of this policy is exaggerated in certain current ex- hortations to hard work, but its existence is ad- mitted by too many trade union leaders ^ to be a matter of doubt. Besides sheer laziness two mo- tives are usually suggested for the restriction of output. There is first the fear of the rate-cutting that has in the past so often followed increases in output. ''Slow down," says Lola Ridge's heroine in The Ghetto, "You'll have him cutting us again!" The second is the notion that somehow the less work is done the more there will be to go around. This is the meaning of a catch phrase from the Ragged Trousered Philanthro- pists:— "Just because we've been working a dam sight too hard, now we've got no work to do." The use of ca'canny or the "stay-in strike" as a conscious form of militant labor policy — either as a weapon in a particular dispute or with the ' Some of them even use it as a text for denouncing the pres- ent industrial system. RESTRICTION AND RESTRICTIONS 179 fixed idea of making capitalism impossible by mak- ing it unprofitable — is another matter and surely of much rarer occurrence. Its classic expression is in The Mmers' Next Step published in 1911 by a group of Welsh miners : — "Lodges should, as far as possible, discard the old method of coming out on strike for any little minor grievance. And adopt the more scientific weapon of the irritation strike by simply remaining at work reducing their output, and so contrive by their general conduct, to make the colliery unremunerative. . . . Use of the irritation strike If the men wish to bring effective pressure to bear, they must use methods which tend to reduce profits. One way of doing this is to decrease production, while continuing at work. Quite a number of instances where this method has been successfully adopted in South Wales could be adduced," - But the very fact that th^ writers felt it neces- sary to explain at such length, even for South Wales readers, what an irritation strike was, is sufficient indication of its rarity. As a means of winning control, it is advocated by only a tiny minority. From the point of view of this inquiry, the subject may be ruled out of the question. Restricting output as a method of piece-work bar- gaining introduces no particularly new principle into the wage bargain. Shirking is not controlling 180 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL industry thougli, like striking, it may be a means towards it. And the ** stay-in strike" is no more, and no less, a means of controlling industry than the ordinary strike and therefore needs no separate treatment here. Restriction of output is more a method of warfare than a form of control and, since this is neither a discussion of the ways of winning control nor of the technique of industrial strife, it is fortunately unnecessary to make any further guesses about the amount of restriction. But if mere restriction of output — for all its interest as an industrial problem and an industrial symptom — ^has no great bearing on the subject, certain specific restrictions are very closely re- lated to control. The Munitions of War Act of 1915 provided (II.4.[3]) that:— **Any rule, practice, or custom not having the force of law which tends to restrict production or employment shall be suspended" ... in the controlled establish- ments. The Government's pledge was given to the trade unions in the famous Treasury Agreement (see next section) that these regulations would be re- stored after the war; the same pledge was a part of the Government's contract with the employers; the employers were under obligation to keep a record of all such changes in practice; and the Restoration (of Pre- War Practices) Act has just RESTRICTION AND RESTRICTIONS 181 made the pledge enforceable at law. Evidently, then, there was an extensive body of custom and vested right in regulations that could at least be held to ''restrict production or employment" and which were considered by the unions, and recog- nized by the Government, as of first-rate im- portance. It is then important to try to estimate how far this mass of confusing, usually local, and often unwritten custom, involved a real — though nega- tive and restrictive — control over the technique of industry. Certain restrictions that were held to fall within the meaning of this clause may be ruled out at once from the present subject, or have been discussed in earlier sections. Limitations on the amount of overtime, for example, were given up for the war emergency; the question is an impor- tant one but surely not primarily one of technique, and its most direct bearing on control has already been discussed under ' ' Unemployment. ' ' Regula- tions forbidding piece work and premium bonus systems were held to come under the Act ; they of course affect industrial technique only indirectly, and were sufficiently covered in the last section. A more important set of these restrictions has to do with the subjects of the ''Right to a Trade" — apprenticeship, demarcation, and the opposition to dilution and the employment of women — re- ferred to in the fifth emotion. These are certainly, 182 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL when enforced, a / direct interference with the ** manipulation of the workman by the employer;" they involve saying which machines shall be run by which sorts of workmen and to that extent imply a real restriction on technique. The restric- tions against dilution are from the point of view of technique especially significant. Demarcation matters less ; a job will be done very much the same way whether it is done by a skilled shipwright or by a skilled boilermaker. But you cannot put a semi-skilled or unskilled man or woman on the work formerly done by a skilled engineer without changing the method of production. You must split up the job into simpler processes, fit the ma- chine with jigs or other fool-proof contrivances, and in general standardize your work so that it can be done on automatic machines. It is just be- cause changes of this sort have been made and found immensely profitable that the issue is so significant. This was the general tendency of ** scientific management" even before the war; the war greatly emphasized the tendency by its demand for standardized munition production. "Industrial methods have been changing," writes Mr. J. T. Murphy in The Workers' Committee, "until the all-round mechanic, for example, is the exception and not the rule. Specialization has progressed by leaps and bounds. Automatic ma- chine production has vastly increased, Appren- RESTRICTION AND RESTRICTIONS 183 ticeship in thousands of cases is a farce, for even the apprentices are kept on repetition work and have become a species of cheap labor. ... It will be thus clearly perceived that every simplification in the methods of production, every application of machinery in place of hand production, means that the way becomes easier for others to enter the trade." This is taken from an argument against craft unionism; it should be somewhat discounted since it is based on engineering, the one industry most affected by the change, and since it is based on war-time experience, when the demand was more standardized than peace-time demand is likely to be. But there is no question whatever that the general movement of industrial technique is towards specialization, and that the trade union rules against dilution are a restriction on that tendency. This control is purely negative, and purely a defence of old customary rights ; the rules were never thought of as implying a right to say what should be done; but it has been suggested that even without the war a demand for positive control would have arisen as a quid pro quo for the yielding of these restrictive regulations. The possibility of the removal of all such restrictions on technique is even stated in a pamphlet written in 1919 as sequel to the Miner's Next Step — the price for removal being positive workers' con- trol:— 184 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL "The disastrous grasping policy of the mine owner has had the result of causing the workmen to erect a code of customs and rules, designed to protect their wages and conditions. These act directly in restraint of pro- duction, as well as of the owners' greed. Remove this code by removing its cause, and the management of a mine loses three-fourths of its worries, while it at least doubles its efficiency." {Industrial Democracy for Miners, p. 11.) I suppose few accounts of restrictions on tech- nique have been written without an emphasis on the objection to machinery. Historically of great interest, it is a nearly dead issue now. In the years 1911, 1912 and 1913, there were two strikes against the introduction of machinery (one of Glass Bottle Makers, the other of Dockers) and one against the use of a portable instead of a sta- tionary drill (Boilermakers). Less than a thou- sand men were directly involved ia these three strikes; as against that 6,500 Ironfounders were in 1912 engaged in a dispute which was settled as follows : — ** Employers' Assurances accepted by men as to im- mediate steps being taken to improve output." No doubt the restrictions on technique have materially interfered with industrial innovations; Mr. Cole speaks of the trade unions in the past as ** extremely bad and partial judges of new indus- RESTRICTION AND RESTRICTIONS 185 trial processes." But it is a mistake to think of trade union regulation of technique as a series of flat negatives and flat opposition to change. That this is not true — that the issue is more often the conditions of change and the right to be consulted and is even sometimes an insistence by the union on improved technique — it is the business of the next two sections to show. XIV TECHNIQUE: CONSULTATION OVER CHANGES A CHANGE in technique is a change in the condi- tions of work. It is therefore natural on the gen- eral principles of collective bargaining to expect to find the claim and practice of consultation over changes in technique. Bargaining over the condi- tions of change is far more important in the pres- ent labor situation than a mere opposition to change. The real objection is to unregulated change. * * The typical dispute is to-day a dispute as to terms," said the "Webbs in 1891; certainly it is no less true now. As long ago as 1864, the Executive of the Ironmoulders advised its members : — "It may go against the grain for us to fraternize with what we consider innovations, but depend upon it, it wiU be our best policy to lay hold of these improve- ments and make them subservient to our best interests. ' ' Apparently fraternizing with innovations now goes less against the trade union grain; in many unions is it a long-established commonplace; in most it is no new thing. Even a conservative old 186 CONSULTATION OVER CHANGES 187 union like the Yorkshire Glass Bottle Makers agrees : — ' * That the workmen are willing to adopt other methods of working than the Yorkshire method, providing satis- factory terms and conditions be agreed upon between the manufacturers and the workmen through their re- presentatives," Laying hold of these improvements and making them subservient — or at least not positively harm- ful— to the workers' interests is a cardinal point in. trade union policy. The unions have used various methods to save their members from the immediate hardships so often connected with changes in technique. The simplest is, of course, merely to secure an under- taking that wages will not be lowered, for example : — < * * The owners shall be at liberty to adopt such improved methods of screening and cleaning as they may consider necessary, provided that any methods so adopted shall not in any way prejudicially effect the wages of the workman." This does not meet the far more serious changes where the fear is that members of the trade will be permanently displaced. An agreement under which the Leek Silk Weavers consented to the in- troduction of two-loom weaving contained the 188 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL ''Employers' Undertaking . . . not to discharge any man in order to initiate the two-loom sys- tem." Another method is to secure an arrange- ment by which the workers who would otherwise have been thrown out of work by a new invention or a new process are secured the first chance to learn and do the new job. The best known example of this was the printing trade; the linotype was introduced in 1894 into the offices of London news- papers under the following agreement : — "All skilled operators . . . shall be members of the London Society of Compositors, preference being given to members of the Companionship into which the ma- chines are introduced. . . . "A Probationary Period of three months shall be allowed the operator to receive his average weekly earn- ings for the previous three months." A strike of Scottish Bookbinders in 1912 secured the principles : — "Qualified tradesmen to have first claim upon all ma- chinery introduced in future displacing qualified male labor and to be paid standard wages." Similar, if less formal, arrangements have been made in other changing trades, as for example in pottery when ''casting" began to replace "press- ing." The conditions under which the unions during CONSULTATION OVER CHANGES 189 the war accepted dilution, and the clause already quoted from the Munition Act forbidding restrictive regulations, are interesting not only- as embodying particular safeguards, e.g. that the "rate for the job" be maintained even if less skilled labor is put on it,^ but because the Act laid down the general principle of the right to consultation on changes in methods of work. Sec- tion 7 of Schedule II reads: — "Due notice shall be given to the workmen concerned wherever practicable of any changes of working con- ditions which it is desired to introduce as a result of the establishment becoming a controlled establishment, and opportunity for local consultation with workmen or their representatives shall be given if desired." The Commissioners on Industrial Unrest (1917) reported that the non-enforcement of this clause — or perhaps the free use of the saving phrase "wherever practicable" — was a cause of unrest. This right to consultation was naturally one of the claims of the shop stewards — a claim evidently enforced while the shortage of labor gave them their opportunity. Their rules at Coventry read as follows on the point : — * It is said that this provision was badly observed, partly be- cause the skilled men were not at all anxious to keep up the dilutees' wages, even though it was for their own after-war in- terest. The attitude more often adopted by trade union officials, however, was to place on " the rate for the job " an interpreta- tion which made diluted labor expensive, so using the rate as a means of hampering dilution. 190 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL "That all proposed changes to existing shop practices and trade union conditions in the shop shall be first notified to the Shop Stewards of that department through the Chief Convenor of Shop Stewards." The great but unrecorded powers of certain en- gineering shop stewards during the war in fact represent the highest degree of the practice of con- sultation. It is true that this consisted largely in fighting over wage questions (as in the case of the Manchester committee that is said to have spent 27 hours of one week in meetings with the man- agement), but it at least involved in practice de- tailed discussion of technical problems and changes and in theory a recognition of a right to consulta- tion over technique. In an extreme case on the Clyde, the steward in each shop, in consultation with the foreman, practically determined the dis- tribution of work within the shop, and similarly the convenor of shop stewards discussed with the works manager the allocation of work between departments and was even shown the firm's books. It even became in this case the custom for notices posted by the manager announcing a change in working rules to be countersigned by the men's representative ; when this was not done, the work- men said: — **It's no signed by MacManus," and disregarded it. It is only here with the recognition of a right CONSULTATION OVER CHANGES 191 or principle of consultation over changes in tech- nique that we come really to control in a proper sense of the word. The former instances are, after all, not much more than special cases of bargain- ing; but an established claim to be coi 5ulted in every technical change is at least the ')asis for considerable control. It is difficult to draw any very valid distinction between consultation and bargaining ; yet consultation over changes in tech- nique very Often may mean more than a mere chance to bargain over terms of a change before it happens; it often means a real, though not always an important, give-and-take of advice and opinion on the advisability of a change. An illus- tration of the most rudimentary form of this might be taken from the experience of a somewhat pater- nalistic forging firm, that had consulted its work- men over some detail of the time-keeping arrange- ments. The attitude of the men is said to have been this: — "The Directors couldn't even do a little thing like that without consulting us." A foreman in one of the National Factories attri- buted the success of his factory and the good feel- ing in it largely to the practice of the management in discussing both with a foremen's and a worker's committee the work ahead and the means of doing it. On a much greater scale the same claim was put forward in the House of Commons by Mr. Brace, one of the Miners' Members, in the impor- 192 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL tant debate on tlie increase of coal prices (July 14, 1919) :— "Why were we not taken into consultation? . . . Very nearly on the last day of the Coal Commission the Miners' Federation of G-reat Britain representatives made an earnest appeal that they should be allowed to co-operate with the Government in finding a way for dealing with the reduction in output, and the reply we had, very much later, was 6/- a ton increase on the price of coal." The same idea is of course a central one of the whole scheme of the Whitley and Works Commit- tees reports, and has perhaps been sufficiently advertised by them. But the right to take a share in the deciding on new industrial processes is a real part of the forward program of an important fraction of the trade union movement. In order to make concrete the references to the actual and proposed recognitions of the ' * right to consultation," I think it is worth while to quote in full the Treasury Agreement of 1915 — on which the Munitions Act and the official Government policy on changes in technique during the war were based — and, for comparison with it, a com- prehensive scheme drawn up by a committee of workers representing the Clyde engineering and shipbuilding trades to meet the same problem of dilution and the changes necessary for war-time CONSULTATION OVER CHANGES 193 production. The first document was the result of a conference between Mr. Lloyd George, then Chan- cellor of the Exchequer, and representatives of the chief munition-making unions. It represented the terms — and the degree of consultation — under which most of the official trade union leaders con- sented to give up for the war their restrictions against dilution. The second scheme was drawn up by Mr. John Muir and other leaders of the shop stewards' movement on the Clyde. It was rejected by the Government — Mr. Lloyd George declaring that he couldn't ''carry on an industrial revolu- tion in the middle of a world war" — and several of its authors were shortly in prison as revolution- ists. The scheme was a war-time one and there- fore did not have to face the problem of unemploy- ment as the background of trade union regula- tions. It is, however, of great interest in tying to- gether the threads of this and the last section — ^the network of restrictions and the conditions of and consultations over their removal — and in pointing the way to the next section — on trade union in- sistences on improvements in technique. It repre- sents a definite attempt on the part of a group of workers to pass from negative to positive, and from obstructive to responsible, control of in- dustry, ' 194 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL THE TREASURY AGREEMENT "The Workmen's Representatives at the Conference will recommend to their members the following proposals with a view to accelerating the output of munitions and equipments of war: — (1) During the war period there shall in no case be any stoppage of work upon munitions and equipments of war or other work required for a satisfactory com- pletion of the war. All differences on wages or conditions of employment arising out of the war shall be dealt with without stop- page in accordance with paragraph (2). Questions not arising out of the war should not be made the cause of stoppage during the war period. (2) Subject to any existing agreements or methods now prevailing for the settlement of disputes, differences of a purely individual or local character shall unless mutually arranged be the subject of a deputation to the firm employing the workmen concerned, and dif- ferences of a general character affecting wages and con- ditions of employment arising out of the war shall be the subject of Conferences between the parties. In all cases of failure to reach a settlement of disputes by the parties directly concerned, or their representa- tives, or under existing agreements, the matter in dis- pute shall be dealt with under any one of the three following alternatives as may be mutually agreed, or, in default of agreement, settled by the Board of Trade. (a) The Committee on Production. (b) A single arbitrator agreed upon by the parties or appointed by the Board of Trade. (c) A court of arbitration upon which Labor is represented equally with the employers. CONSULTATION OVER CHANGES 195 (3) An Advisory Committee representative of the organized workers engaged in production for Govern- ment requirements shall be appointed by the Government for the purpose of facilitating the carrying out of these recommendations and for consultation by the Govern- ment or by the workmen concerned. (4) Provided that the conditions set out in paragraph (5) are accepted by the Government as applicable to all contracts for the execution of war munitions and equipments, the workmen's representatives at the Con- ference are of opinion that during the war period the relaxation of the present trade practices is imperative, and that each Union be recommended to take into fav- orable consideration such changes in working conditions or trade customs as may be necessary with a view to accelerating the output of war munitions or equip- ments. (5) The reconmiendations contained in paragraph (4) are conditional on the Government requiring all con- tractors and sub-contractors engaged on munitions and equipments of war or other work required for the satis- factory completion of the war to give an undertaking to the following effect: — Any departure during the war from the practice rul- ing in our workshops, shipyards, and other industries prior to the war, shall only be for the period of the war. No change in practice made during the war shall be allowed to prejudice the position of the work people in our employment or of their Trade Unions in regard to the resumption and maintenance after the war of any rules or customs existing prior to the war. In any readjustment of staff which may have to be effected after the war, priority of employment will be 196 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL given to workmen in our employment at the beginning of the war who are serving with the colors or who are now in our employment. Where the custom of a shop is changed during the war by the introduction of semi-skilled men to perform work hitherto performed by a class of workmen of higher skill, the rates paid shall be the usual rates of the district for that class of work. The relaxation of existing demarcation restrictions or admission of semi-skilled or female labor shall not affect adversely the rates customarily paid for the job. In cases where men who ordinarily do the work are ad- versely affected thereby, the necessary readjustments shall be made so that they can maintain tlieir previous earnings. A record of the nature of the departures from the conditions prevailing before the date of this undertak- ing shall be kept and shall be open for inspection by the authorized representative of the Government. Due notice shall be given to the workmen concerned, wherever practicable, of any changes of working con- ditions which it is desired to introduce as the result of this arrangement, and opportunity of local consultation with the men or their representatives shall be given if desired. All differences with our workmen engaged on Govern- ment work arising out of changes so introduced, or with regard to wages or conditions of employment arising out of the war, shall be settled without stoppage of work in accordance with the procedure laid down in paragraph (2). It is clearly understood that, except as expressly pro- vided in the fourth paragraph of clause 5, nothing in CONSULTATION OVER CHANGES 197 this undertaking is to prejudice the position of employ- ers or employees after the war. D. Lloyd George. Walter Runeiman. Arthur Henderson (Chairman of Workmen's Representatives). Wm. Mosses (Secretary of Workmen's Representatives). March 19, 1915. THE CLYDE DILUTION SCHEME "The Clyde District Committee of the Federation of Engineering and Shipbuilding Trades, which repre- sents all the workers in the industries mentioned, are ready to co-operate with the Admiralty Shipyard Labor Committee for the Clyde in accelerating all work required by that Department, wherever possible, in the national emergency. We believe that with greater co-ordination and better distribution of labor, the present admittedly high stand- ard of output can be further improved upon. Therefore it is agreed that: — • (1) The existing members of the Unions affiliated to the Federation will be used to the best advantage. (2) If at any time the Central Board hereinafter men- tioned are satisfied that any rule or custom tends to re- strict output, it shall be suspended for the duration of the war. (3) Pneumatic, hydraulic, electric, oxy-acetylene and all other time and labor-saving devices will be adopted and used to the fullest practicable extent. (4) There shall be interchangeability of work between the members of any particular Union affiliated to the 198 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL Federation and to effect that purpose all lines of de- marcation between members of that Union shall be suspended for the period of the War. (5) For the period of the War all allocation of work between the different Shipyard Unions will be sus- pended, and the work performed by the members of the Shipyard Unions will be interchangeable, it being agreed that any work of one Shipyard Union performed by the members of another Shipyard Union shall not form any precedent after the War. (6) When in any particular trade men are unobtain- able, and the work is of such a character, or the con- ditions such as to enable the labor introduced to per- form the work with reasonable efficiency, skilled men from allied trades and semi-skilled and unskilled men and (where the work is appropriate and the conditions and surroundings are suitable to their sex) women may be introduced into the trade of the Unions affiliated to the Federation. (7) The relaxation of existing demarcation restric- tions or admission of semi-skilled or female labor shall not affect adversely the rates customarily paid for job. In cases where men who ordinarily do the work are adversely affected thereby, the necessary readjustment shall be made so that they can maintain their previous earnings. (8) Labor introduced under Clause 6 to do any work of the Unions affiliated to the Federation shall be under the supervision of the foreman of the work. (9) Where overtime is required on any job of the members of the Unions affiliated to the Federation, to which labor has been introduced under Clause 6, any members of the Unions affiliated to the Federation em- ployed thereon shall have equality of treatment. CONSULTATION OVER CHANGES 199 (10) In the event of any member of any particular Union affiliated to the Federation being available for emplojnnent at his own occupation he shall have the preference. (11) A record of the nature of any departure in any shipbuilding, or ship-repairing establishment from the conditions prevailing when the establishment became a controlled establishment shall be kept, and, so far as the departure affects any Unions affiliated to the Federation, copies shall be handed to the Society concerned and the Central Board hereinafter mentioned. (12) Due notice of any intended change of practice in any shipbuilding or ship-repairing establishment shall be given to the Shop Stewards of the Union con- cerned with their Union representatives. (13) Facilities shall be given by the employers to the shop committees to meet when necessary for the pur- poses of this scheme. (14) All differences arising out of, or in connection with this agreement shall, without stoppage of work, be promptly referred to and settled between the Cen- tral Board and the Shipyard Labor Committee of the Admiralty. (15) Under the scheme of transfer no workman or workwoman shall suffer any pecuniary loss when trans- ferred from one Admiralty firm to another; they shall receive the standard Trade Union district rate of wages, if on time or piece, plus travelling allowances according to the War Munitions Volunteer scheme; in the event of being transferred to work paid at a lower rate than his or her own rate, the original rate shall be paid; this practice shall also be carried out in cases of transfer from one department to another in an Ad- miralty firm, or from one district to another. 200 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL For the purposes of this scheme the Federation will establish Shop Committees in the various yards and engine shops in the Clyde area, under the direction and control of a Central Board, which will co-operate with the Shipyard Labor Committee of the Admiralty, to co-ordinate all efforts for the acceleration of output. Shop Committees to consist of Shop Stewards now representing the various Unions in the shops and yards affiliated to the Federation. Where the present number of Shop Stewards in any one yard is inadequate, the Societies concerned will immediately instruct their mem- bers to appoint a representative by election in the shop or yard where there is a deficiency, for the purposes of this scheme. The duties of Shop Committees shall be to report where : — (1) An unnecessary supply of labor prevails; (2) In the department labor can be more effectively employed by distribution, transfer, or other- wise; (3) Machinery can be more usefully employed; (4) Machinery can be usefully introduced; (5) Any other proposals regarded as being condu- cive to the acceleration of output; (6) The Committees will each appoint a represen- tative steward, who will notify the Secretary of the Central Board immediately it is thought that increased output can be secured in any direction. The duties of the Central Board, which will be appointed by and be responsible to the Federation, shall be to investigate all cases and suggestions submitted to them by the authorized Shop Committee, and to co- CONSULTATION OVER CHANGES 201 operate with the Admiralty Board, with a view to the more effective employment of labor and machinery in any manner deemed necessary. The Central Board shall also be the Board to whom complaint shall be made with re- gard to grievances arising out of the appli- cation of the foregoing scheme." XV TECHNIQUE: INSISTENCE ON IMPROVEMENTS The unions have blocked certain changes in technique which they thought would injure their interests. The unions have laid down conditions under which changes in technique might be made without injuring their interests. These are real forms of control over technique but of negative control. At the end of the last section there was a suggestion — in the demands for consultation for its own sake and in the proposals of the Clyde Committee — of a positive interest in planning the technique of industry. We have discussed the workers' negative interference in technique and their claim to consultation over technique ; it is the business of this section to study the cases of work- ers' insistence on improvements in technique. Some interest in good technique is a natural outcome of a highly-developed system of piece rates in which rate-cutting is prevented. If the piece workers' earnings depend on the efficiency of the machines or the quality of the material sup- plied or the arrangement of the factory, the work- er's '* facilities " may naturally become a part of 202 INSISTENCE ON IMPROVEMENTS 203 the bargain and the union secretary may even find himself acting as a semi-ofiicial efficiency inspector. This was the origin of the long-standing ''bene- volence ' ' of the cotton unions toward new machin- ery of which the Webbs wrote as follows : — "In Lancashire it quickly becomes a grievance in the Cotton Trade Unions, if any one employer, or any one district, falls behind the rest No employer takes the trouble to induce the laggards in his own industry to keep up with the march of invention. Their falling behind is indeed an immediate advantage to himself. But to the Trade Unions, representing all the operatives, the sluggishness of the poor or stupid employers is a serious danger. The old-fashioned master spinners, with slow-going family concerns, complain bitterly of the harshness with which the Trade Union officials refuse to make any allowance for their relatively imperfect machinery, and even insist, as we have seen, on their paying positively a higher piece-work rate if they do not work their mills as efficiently as their best-equipped competitors. Thus, the Amalgamated Association of Operative Cotton-spinners, instead of obstructing new machinery, actually penalizes the employer who fails to introduce it. ' ' "Penalizes" is a word that may suggest too much; the situation is that the unions allow a re- duction in piece-work price for the introduction of more efficient machinery, the effect is to encourage improvements. It thus becomes the business of the union secretary to investigate claims of bad ma- 204 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL chinery or bad material (the ''bad spinning" dis- putes) or, in fact, any inefficiencies in management that affect the worker's output, and to get them set right or paid for. Somewhat similar principles govern the piece-work arrangements of the Boiler- makers. Their first national agreement admitted that the employer was ''entitled to a revision of rates on account of labor-saving devices ' ' and for ' ' improved arrangements in yards. ' ' On the other hand, the present arrangements provide for the settlement of complaints from the side of the men "with respect to insufficiency of pressure, char- acter of tools, inefficiency of plant, or obstructed or odd jobs." A number of strikes have turned on this relation of industrial technique to piece-rate earnings. One of the terms of a settlement in a strike of nearly 10,000 workers in the Paisley thread mills, in 1907, was as follows : — "Improvements made in arrangements of machinery enabling higher wages to be earned." The similar effect of an Ironf ounders ' strike — in enforcing better technique — has already been mentioned. The Miners illustrate several of the steps be- tween complaints over facilities and actual respon- sibility for the organization of industry. The is- INSISTENCE ON IMPROVEMENTS 205 sue again starts with piece work. The hewer is paid for the amount of coal that gets to the sur- face; that depends in large part on the supply of tubs and the arrangements for haulage. Time spent underground waiting for tubs and the num- ber of days the pit is closed for lack of the nec- essary facilities,^ are of direct bearing on the miners' wage. These are by no means new com- plaints— a fact worth remembering now that the output of coal is a subject of public passion and Parliament is debating pit-props. Sir Eichard Redmayne, His Majesty's Chief Inspector of Mines, reminded the Coal Commission that com- plaints by the workers of lack of tubs, trams, etc. had been coming in to his department for years. These complaints were by no means ended by the passing of the Minimum Wage Act of 1912. The management can still turn the workers back at the pithead when there is no work, and the minimum rates are set below what a man would naturally earn with good facilities, although one Miners' agent quotes an official's remark — ''What do you care? You're on the 'min'l" — to a work- man complaining of some defect in management. For the sake of concreteness, it is worth while to list some of the specific complaints made by the Miners' leaders, national and local:— too little *C/. the claims of the United Mine Workers of America in their recent strike. 206 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL coal-cutting machinery ; too little mechanical haul- age ; shortage of trains, tubs, rails, horses, and of timber for pit-props; bad condition of roads; wagons too big to go through the passageways; bad distribution of tubs and wagons ; bad distribu- tion of rolling stock. Charges of this sort were frequently referred to in the course of the hearings before the Coal Com- mission.^ Mr. Herbert Smith gave figures of the results of an inquiry into shortage of tubs, etc. in 300 Yorkshire pits (Q.27759), and Mr. Hodges spoke of the ''thousands of instances" of faulty transport facilities " that were submitted to the Executive Committee of the South Wales Miners ' Federation when they were putting up their scheme for increased output" (Q. 7178). Three references are well worth quoting: — "Mr. SmUlie. Hardly a day passes but what we get letters signed from one or other colliery complaining that the men have been sent home day after day or are in the pit and are only doing half work, and in some col- lieries there would be 400 or 500 tons more a day if there could be a clearance. . . . Sir Richard Redmayne. I have not the least doubt in the world you are getting such letters; I get such letters. ... I have here case after case of detailed enquiry into such eases. Sometimes I found there was no shadow of truth in them, sometimes I found there •EspedaUy Questions 7168, 7178, 7183, 26994, 26995, 27469, 27472, 27759-27790. INSISTENCE ON IMPROVEMENTS 207 was. ... I cannot think that is the whole truth, namely, that the cause of the decline in output is attributable to want of clearance — partially, yes." (Q. 27007.) *'Mr. Hodges. This is the report of the check weigher to his Committee [at a Lancashire colliery] : — 'For the last three months I have been continually bombarding the management for reasons as to the shortage of tubs, etc., which the men are constantly complaining about. During my investigation I found there have been stoppages of the main haulage roads through having day-work men working on the haulage getting the roof down and stopping gangs whilst the tubs were filled with dirt. On May 15th [1919] four men came out of the Trencherbone Mine as a protest far the manner in which they were being treated in regard to empty tubs. It was 12 o'clock noon when they got to the surface, and they had not had any empty tub from 11 o'clock of the previous day. Their tally num- ber is 63. For the last few weeks the men in the Cran- berry Mine have been having a bad time of it owing to the shortage of tubs. ... I have spoken to the fire- men. They say they are ashamed to go among the men who have to get their time over the best way possible.' ! " (Q. 27472.) "Mr Hodges. Do you know the Nine Mile Point Col- liery? Mr. Winstone [President South Wales Miners' Fed- eration]. Very well. Mr. Hodges. Do you remember the workmen at that colliery had to embark on a strike at one time because 208 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL the management were developing the worst seams in the colliery and leaving the best seams until the market con- ditions were better and the control lifted? Mr. Winstone. Yes, they urged the colliery company to develop a piece of coal which was nearer to the col- liery, and admitted to be better coal, and which could not be developed on account of the opposition of the royalty owner." (Q. 23677-23678.) The present point is not how far these charges are justified or how far they explain reduced out- put. Their real significance for this inquiry is in showing to what extent the actual problems of man- agement and business discretion have been made subjects of trade union demands. The Miners, then, have a long record of insis- tences on detailed improvements in the method of working. One by-product of the war was to give these complaints something of a responsible status. The Miners ' Federation was asked by the Grovern- ment to set up Absentee Committees, such as those already mentioned, to punish the men who stayed away from work. In most districts the Miners refused to do so except on condition that these com- mittees should also have power to criticize the man- agement when it was at fault in not providing fac- ilities : if the worker is to be punished for staying away from work, their argument ran, why not the officials for keeping the men idle by mismanage- ment? The agreement of May 16, 1916, between INSISTENCE ON IMPROVEMENTS 209 the Executive Committee of the Miners' Federa- tion and the Parliamentary Committee of the Min- ing Association, under which the committees were set up, recognized this dual function: — * ' That in regard to absenteeism this meeting agrees to the matter being referred to the districts, on the distinct understanding that Committees will at once be set up in each district to devise and put into operation effective machinery to secure the attendance of all the workmen employed to the fullest extent, and to inquire into the circumstances of workmen employed at the mine not being provided with work when they have presented themselves at the mine, the intention being to secure, as far as possible, the output of coal necessary for the country's needs." The local application of this principle is well illus- trated by a miner's account of a large meeting of coal-owners and Miners' delegates at Stoke-on- Trent:— "The meeting of representatives of employers and employed soon became lively and it showed the intense interest that was taken in the Government suggestions, and the men pointed out to the Coal Owners that there were other causes which caused a reduced output of coal besides absenteeism: — the faults of the management in allowing the miners to wait for timber, no facilities in taking men to their work and bringing them back, the waiting for tubs through scarcity and uneven distribu- tion of the same. If they were going to work this 210 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL scheme and draw up rules, they must bring the man- agement in as well as the men." A specimen of the provisions for enforcing this side of the agreement may be taken from the rules of the North Staffordshire Output Committees : — "It shall be open to the Pit Committee to consider the facilities for output, and for the provision of mate- rial necessary for the proper performance of their work by the workmen, and to report thereon. If the report of the Committee imputes negligence on the part of any official of the mine, a written copy shall be forwarded to the manager, who shall take such steps as he shall deem necessarj', in the circumstances, and shall inform the Committee in writing of the action he has taken, it being understood that it is the intention for the manager and his officials to afford all possible reasonable facilities for output. If the Committee shall not be in agreement that the steps taken by the manager are satisfactory, it shall then deal with the case as if the alleged negligence were a breach of the Rules, and failing agreement the matter should be reported to the Central Committee for decision. . . . The Central Committee shall consider and advise upon steps to be taken to the further improvement of output and of maintaining an increased attendance." The provisions for imposing fines for bad atten- dance and for working out fines by subsequent good attendance were similar to those quoted from the Cleveland ironworks. So much for the scheme on paper; it repre- INSISTENCE ON IMPROVEMENTS 211 sents at least a definite and admitted claim (if only for the period of the war) on the part of the Miners to the right to insist on technical efficiency. It is harder to say how much it meant in practice. The attempt to set up the committees was general on the part of the Miners' leaders ; at a number of pits they were unsuccessful. Moreover, the ef- fectiveness of the committees ' work varied greatly, though there is no doubt that on the whole atten- dance was considerably increased. Nor did the committees in all cases undertake all the functions suggested above; Lancashire, for example, would not take the responsibility of finding. Of more importance for the present point is the fact that many of the committees failed to carry into force the insistence on improved facilities. It is true that Yorkshire reached the point of fining negligent officials and that many committees reported im- provements ''which affected the output of coal and increased the wages of the men" or a greater keenness on the part of the mines officials to make sure that no time was lost. Perhaps the most strik- ing case in which positive responsibility for tech- nique was assumed by the Miners was at a York- shire pit, in which the men appointed a controller to supervise the distribution of tubs underground and paid half his wages. Mr. Herbert Smith, the Vice-President of the Miners ' Federation, put the case before the Coal Commission : — 212 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL "The Mitchel Main employs 1,750 men. I have a let- ter from a man who was appointed coal controller, down the pit. I will read you this letter . . . 'Our mem- bers have been below the district's day's work and some below the minimum on account of the shortage of tubs. We can prove this statement and our management can- not deny it. . . . We have gone to the lengths of ap- pointing a controller and paid half his wages from our check, and Mr. Edward J. Peace was appointed to that position and during the time he was down the mine or- ganizing the distribution of coal and everything, the output was a good deal better.' , . . Men were rather anxious when they paid a man out of their own pockets to organize?" (Q. 27788.) But on the other hand many committees were met with solid opposition in their attempts to con- sider problems of management. In South Wales the scheme fell through entirely because of dis- agreement over the scope of the inquiry. The story and the disputed clause in the men's scheme came out before the Coal Commission in the discussion between Mr. Hodges of the South Wales Miners' Federation and Mr. Hugh Bramwell representing the South Wales coal-owners :— *'Mr. Hodges. I also had the privilege of drafting a scheme for the establishment of Joint Committees in South Wales, to which I referred when you were in the box last, and I remember very distinctly the scheme coming before you, and you rejected it. You agreed to several clauses. When it came to this clause you re- jected it? INSISTENCE ON IMPROVEMENTS 213 Mr. Bramwell. Yes; we went to the Coal Controller about that. Mr. Hodges. Here the workmen made certain propo- sitions to you which they thought would be really helpful? Mr. BramweU. Yes; they interfered with the man- agement. Mr. Hodges. I will read them. ' The Committee shall receive reports from the Management and Workmen on matters affecting output, such as: (a) Shortage of trams and road materials. (b) Shortage of, or unsuitable, timber. (c) Bad haulage roads and inadequate haulage. (d) And any other cause which in their opinion is likely to interfere with the smooth working of the mine or interfere with the production of the largest output.' You rejected the scheme because it contained that clause ? Mr. Bramwell. That was, I think, one clause we ob- jected to. We went to the Coal Controller with you about it. The Coal Controller offered us the scheme which was accepted by the bulk of the other coalfields. It was you who rejected that. Mr. Hodges. Certainly. I remember it and I con- fess it because the Coal Controller's scheme was felt by the South Wales Miners that it did not give them ? Mr. Bramwell. Because it did not give them power to interfere with the management. Mr. Hodges. That is so. Not to interfere with the manager in his work, but it did not give them power to make suggestions as to how the work should be carried on successfully? 214 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL Mr. Bramwell. It was not a question of suggestions. ' ' (Q. 21186-21190.) Moreover the principle of the right to make tech- nical criticisms was not always enforced even where formally conceded. In some cases the work- ers* side did not dare bring up the question or else simply let their opportunities pass. And a large number of committees definitely broke down in disputes over this issue. This experience is worth setting out in such de- tail, because it brings us again to a consciously felt "frontier of control." The quality of the innova- tion that this trade union insistence on technique implied may be indicated by the grounds on which it was opposed by a minority of miners and a num- ber of managers. Some of the former called it doing the employer's work. "When the miners' leaders began to draw the miners ' attention to the loss of turns and pointed out to them that, if they only increased their attendance a little, it would increase the output by 13 million tons of coal, they soon told their leaders that it was the business of the employer to talk like that." Trade union offi- cials were not paid for ' ' advocating increased out- put which would only affect the coal-owner." On the other hand, as shown in Mr. Bramwell 's testi- mony; managers felt that it was interfering with management and taking the management out of INSISTENCE ON IMPROVEMENTS 215 their hands. When a trade union is found vigor- ously doing the employer's work and taking it out of the management's hands, the case comes very near the center of the problem of control. It is this background of quarrels and responsi- bilities regarding problems of actual production that makes somewhat less astonishing the part played by the Miners' Federation in the Coal Com- mission's inquiry. Their claim was not merely that the mine-workers should have higher wages and shorter hours ; but that these demands could be met by improving the organization of the in- dustry; and that the Miners were prepared both to suggest and to help carry out the necessary im- provements. Detailed evidence of the technical defects of the industry was a more important part of the Miners' case than even the reports of the conditions of their housing.^ *'I want the mines nationalized," said Mr. Smillie on the occasion of a recent deputation to the Prime Minister, '*in order that, by the fullest possible development on intelligent lines, with the assistance of the en- gineering power which we know we possess and the inventions which we know we pos- sess, we might largely develop the mines and increase the output. That is one of our first claims." • E.g., Coal Commission Evidence, vol. I, pp. 321-322. 216 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL These cases in which the organized pressure of the trade unions is on the side of improvements in technique are emphasized, not as of frequent oc- currence outside the industries named, but as the furthest extensions of constructive control. There are other instances of suggestions for improve- ment made by groups of workers still to be con- sidered; the present section deals only with those in which improved technique has been definitely something for the trade union to fight for. XVI TECHNIQUE: SUGGESTIONS AND INVENTIONS The positive interferences in technique already mentioned had their beginnings, at least, in the demand for facilities for piece-work earnings. I do not mean that this is the only factor ; the signi- ficant transition in motives from wages to work- manship has already been suggested. Still the be- ginnings were piece work, and the interferences were backed by the organized force of the unions. There are, however, other cases of an interest on the part of groups of workers in the betterment of technique which are not so immediately bound up with piece-work earnings and which are not to the same extent enforced by the unions. They are not, then, insistences on improvements; they are better classed as suggestions and inventions. Not as significant from the point of view of con- trol as those just mentioned, they are, neverthe- less, interesting as indicating some degree of joint action in the development of industrial technique. The work of the individual inventor is beside our point, except as he is encouraged and protected by collective action. I heard a group of Midland 217 218 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL working-class students debating with great inter- est the encouragement and protection of inven- tors and the state of the patent laws ; they made no suggestion that it might be a subject for trade union and works committee action. Similarly the various schemes of individual firms for encourag- ing inventions and suggestions, — from the mere provision of ' ' suggestion boxes ' ' to the long-stand- ing and successful systems of awards for inven- tions in force at William Denny's shipbuilding yard at Dumbarton and at Barr and Stroud's en- gineering works at Glasgow and the similar scheme introduced in March, 1919, at Cadbury's cocoa works at Bourneville which produced 759 sug- gestions in the first seven months — are not cases of workers' control; though it is hardly a coincidence that the first firm mentioned was, as pointed out by D. F. Schloss, a pioneer in devolu- tion of responsibility to groups of workers and that all three have highly developed works com- mittees. A works committee is of course hardly likely to make inventions ; that is not a political function. It may, as the Ministry of Labor's report on Works Committees suggests, do two things: — (1) create an atmosphere which will encourage the making of suggestions and (2) provide the machinery, by sub-committee or otherwise, for stimulating an interest in and for considering and testing inven- SUGGESTIONS AND INVENTIONS 219 tions. As an illustration of the need for the first, the former labor superintendent of an engineering firm told me of a man who had been victimized by his foreman for suggesting to the manager an im- provement in process. A sub-committee with a part of the latter function has just (October, 1919) been set up at Cadbury's at the suggestion of the workers' side of the Works Council. It is called the ''Brains Committee" and its object is to hunt for promising talent among the employees. The works manager describes it as the ''most talked-of thing in the works. ' ' The encouragement of inventions was clearly intended as an important part of the Whitley scheme. The following is a typical clause from the list of functions of a Joint Industrial Council : — "The provision of facilities for the full consideration and utilization of inventions and improvements designed by work people and for the adequate safeguarding of the rights of the designers of such improvements." (Paint Color and varnish Industry.) So much for inventions proper; there is still the field of suggestions in regard to meeting the various practical problems of organization and the planning of work. This is obviously a more natural subject for group action than the former ; of this sort were the suggestions made by the Out- put Committees referred to in the last section. 220 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL Many works committees have discussed the actual arrangement of work ; the report by the Ministry of Labor says that ''testimony to the value of suggestions [made by them] . . . has been received from employers." The suggestions reported were usually on minor matters of detail; in one inter- esting case, however, a committee of pattern-mak- ers suggested, as an alternative to dilution, the pur- chase of certain tools and brought about a 50% increase of output/ A recent instance is even more striking. The British Westinghouse Co. was considering closing do^vn its foundry on account of the high cost of production. The works manager put the proposal before his shop stewards' committee. The committee ob- jected and asked for two weeks in which to collect statistics of wages in other foundries in order to show that the high cost of production was not due to high wages. These figures were pre- sented and indicated that the wages in the foundry were, if anything, lower than in competing ones. The committee argued that this showed that the trouble was one of organization and asked for an- other two weeks in which to prepare suggestions. At the end of that time the committee presented a memorandum on foundry organization — which the works manager described as the ablest he had ' p. 30, Works Committees, Industrial Report No. 2, Ministry of Labor. SUGGESTIONS ANt> INVENTIONS 221 ever seen, and the firm has decided to keep the foundry going and to spend hundreds of pounds in carrying out the committee's suggestions. The encouragement of suggestions is of course an integral part of the Whitley idea. The third re- port of the Whitley committee says of the works committees : — "They should always keep in the forefront the idea of constructive co-operation in the improvement of the industry to which they belong. Suggestions of all kinds tending to improvement should be frankly welcomed and freely discussed. Practical proposals should be exam- ined from all points of view. There is an undeveloped asset of constructive ability — ^valuable alike to the in- dustry and to the State — awaiting the means of reali- zation. ' ' These read like merely pious and peace-loving phrases; the argument from the waste of ability in a system which discourages suggestions, how- ever, I have heard from both sides, — from the head of the labor department of a manufacturers* association ; from a foreman in one of the National Factories where suggestions had been taken from both the foremen's and the workmen's com- mittees, and, most strikingly, in Mr. William Straker's evidently sincere reference before the Coal Commission to the ''coal-owners' huge blun- der" in neglecting to use the practical ability of the men. "For a generation," says the first 222 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL Sankey report (signed by the Chairman and three employer members of the Coal Commission), **the colliery worker has been educated socially and technically. The result is a great national asset. Why not use it?" These are mainly arguments for what might be ; the actual instances of workers' activity under this head amount to comparatively little. The organization of the facilities for invention and suggestions may become an important function of joint committees. It implies a direct assumption of a degree of interest in and responsibility for technique. At the moment, however, it is a much less significant form of workers ' control than that collective enforcing of industrial efficiency men- tioned under the ** Insistence on Improvements." XVII TRADE POLICY: JOINT ACTION Thebe are still other people who write about control who make a distinction similar to that used in the transition from discipline to technique Their argument runs like this: — The workers should have much to say about the immediate processes of production, which are the stuff of their daily life ; but general trade policy — ^buying and selling, exchange, the market, the adjustment of supply and demand, large-scale research and planning — is obviously not their business. Again the moral may be disregarded and the distinction used for classification. Again, however, it must be recognized that it is not a rigid one: — unem- ployment, for example, is clearly a matter of gen- eral trade policy; there is no sharply logical line that sets off the invention of a device invented for use in a particular shop, from the organization of research for a great industry. And it will again be seen, in this and the following section, that the unions have not kept neatly to one side of the demarcation laid down in the theory. The present section will consider cases in which the unions have acted jointly with the employers in these 228 224 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL matters; the next with cases of independent ac- tion or demands on the part of the workers, A loose sort of joint action between employers* and workmen's organizations for the common pur- poses of their industries is of course no new thing. A rudimentary provision for it — ^now superseded by a Joint Industrial Council — is found in the rules of the conciliation boards in the building trades : — "Although the principal objects of the Conciliation Boards are the settlement of disputes . . ., it shall also be within their province to meet and discuss any question of trade interest at the request of any of the parties to the agreement." Apparently legislation was one of the trade ques- tions intended. The Plumbers' board made this object more specific: — "To consider any question affecting the Plumbing trade and to procure the improvement of any existing laws, usages and customs, which the Bosrd may consider to be prejudicial to the trade, and to amend or oppose legislation or other measures or the establishment of any usages or customs which in the opinion of the Board might prejudicially affect our Craft." The cotton industry gives the best examples of this sort of joint action. The Oldham agreement reads : — TRADE POLICY: JOINT ACTION 225 "It is agreed that in respect to the opening of new markets abroad, the alteration of restrictive foreign tariffs and other similar matters which may benefit or injure the cotton trade, the same shall be dealt with by a Committee of three or more from each Federation, all the Associations agreeing to bring the whole weight of their influence to bear in furthering the general interests of the cotton industry in this country." This clause has not been at all a dead letter; as witness the recent project of a trip to India and the United States by a party of cotton manufac- turers and union leaders, and the well-known readiness with which both sides of the cotton in- dustry will rally against Government interference — or answer the cry of Lancashire against London. The logical, though infrequent, extension of the sort of co-operation suggested in the agreement mentioned is definite combination to fix prices ** thereby securing better profits to manufacturers and better profits to work people ' ' at the consum- er's expense or to secure tariff or other preferen- tial advantages. The former is evidently aimed at in the rules of the conciliation board for china manufacture : — ** Mutual Trade Alliance. ... No Member of the Manufacturers' Association shall employ any workman who is not a Member of the Operatives' Association, and no workman shall take employment under any manu- facturer who is not a Member of the Manufacturers' 226 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL Association, or who is selling his goods at lower prices than those which from time to time are decided upon." (Italics mine.) The ** Birmingham Alliances," in six branches of the light metal trades, contain the same arrange- ment and the definite stipulation that prices are to be set by a ''Wages Board, to be formed of an equal number of employers and employed. ' ' The latter object — combination for trade war purposes — is sometimes said to be a main part of the Whit- ley scheme. ''His (the Minister of Labor's) idea," said a trade union journal, "appears to be that joint bodies of employers and employed will be excellent institutions to conduct a trade war after the war." Some color is given to this view by the activity of one or two of the Joint Coun- cils in asking for tariff advantages^ and " anti- dumping" laws. It is not fair, however, to suggest this as the only motive behind the Whitley scheme or even its chief outlet for joint action on trade policy. The first stated object of a Joint Industrial Council usually reads something like this: — ' Cf., the sneer in one of the Daily Herald's " Hymns of Re- construction,"— "Whitley Councils. Two opposite sides, Two opposite sides, See how they agree. See how they agree! They both are after Protection for trade That is the way that profits are made: No better example of mutual aid Than two opposite sides." TRADE POLICY: JOINT ACTION 227 "To secure the largest possible measure of joint action between the employers and work people for the safe- guarding and development of the industry as a part of national life." (Bobbin and Shuttle Making Industry.) The proposal by Mr. Malcolm Sparkes, a Lon- don master builder, which led to the formation of the Joint Industrial Council for the building trades began as follows:— "The interests of employers and employed are in many respects opposed; but they have a common inter- est in promoting the efficiency and status of the service in which they are engaged and in advancing the well- being of its personnel." And the phrase — "the industry as a national service" — ^has at least got from the building trades constitution into the conversation of local leaders. How much all this means in practice it is too early to say. It is worth while, however, to look at some of the specific functions suggested under the head of this broad generalization. "The consideration of measures for regularizing production and employ- ment" and the provisions for encouraging and protecting inventors have been mentioned in earl- ier sections. The Council for the Silk Industry (among others) provides for: — * ' The regular consideration of, and the compilation of, available . statistics as to wages, working costs, fluctua- 228 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL tions in the cost of materials and Customs tariffs, and the study and promotion of scientific and practical sys- tems of account keeping." A number of constitutions have clauses such as the following:— "The encouragement of study and research with a view to the improvement and perfection of the quality of the product, and of machinery and methods of eco- nomical manufacture in all branches of the industry." (Match Manufacturing Industry.) The program for the building trades council already quoted was even more specific in stating a similar object : — "Continuous and Progressive Improvement — To pro- vide a Clearing House for ideas, and to investigate, in conjunction with experts, every suggested line of im- provement including, for example, such questions as: — Industrial Control and Status of Labor. Scientific Management and Increase of Output. Welfare Methods. Closer association between commercial and aesthetic requirements. ' ' It is again too early to say bow much these proj- ects mean. A sub-committee of the Building Trades Parliament is making an attempt to pro- vide the basis for a complete reorganization of the industry. Its interim report on Organized Public Service in the Building Industry,^ known as the ' See Note on Sources. TRADE POLICY: JOINT ACTION 229 *' Foster Report," has already been referred to under ''Unemployment." Its recommendations, however, go much further than was there in- dicated. In addition to the provisions for making unemployment a charge on the industry and for the regularization of employment, the report rec- ommends a regulation of the Wages of Manage- ment (on lines admittedly not yet worked out), a limitation and guarantee by the industry as a whole of the rate of interest on capital, and the disposal of the surplus earnings of the industry at the discretion of the Council. The detailed pro- visions under the last two heads are as follows : — '*The Hiring of Capital. 36. We recommend that approved capital, invested in the Building Industry, and registered annually after audit, shall receive a limite-d but guaranteed rate of in- terest, bearing a definite relation to the average yield of the most remunerative Government Stock. The fixing of the ratio will have to be worked out by further in- vestigation, but we recommend that once determined upon, the guarantee shall apply to all firms in the Industry, except where failure to earn the aforesaid rate is declared by the Committee on the advice of the auditors to be due to incompetent management. . . . The Surplus Earnings of the Industrff. 40. . . . We, therefore, recommend: (a) That the amount of the surplus earnings of the Industry shall be publicly declared every year, and accompanied by a schedule of the services to which the money has been voted. 230 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL (b) That it shall be held in trust by a National Joint Committee of the Building Trades In- dustrial Council, and shall be applied to the following common services, which will be de- veloped under the control of the Industry as a whole: — 1. Guarantee of Interest on approved capital, as outlined in paragraph 36. 2. Loans to firms in the Industry for purposes of development. 3. Education and research in various directions for improvement of the Industry, both in- dependently and in co-operation with other industries. 4. Superannuation scheme for the whole regis- tered personnel of the Industry, 5. Replacement of approved capital lost through no fault of the management. 6. Such other purposes as may be thought ad- visable. ' ' This project was vigorously and seriously debated at one meeting of the Building Trades Parliament and has been referred back to the same Commit- tee for further consideration. All these things mean the possibility of joint action, though in most cases they mean little activity on the part of the rank and file of work- ers, on a wide field of questions. For a review of the present situation in regard to control, how- ever, they must be heavily discounted. In the older forms of joint action, those that are more TRADE POLICY: JOINT ACTION 231 purely for the sake of protection or prices, there is little evidence of labor acting as anything but a very junior partner; the newer forms are still almost entirely on paper. This does not at all exhaust the account of cases of joint action on matters of business policy. As has already been suggested in earlier sections — for example in the account of the Westinghouse works committee's advice on foundry organization — certain individual firms have given opportuni- ties for discussion at least on questions that would surely be classed under the heading of trade policy. A number of firms make the practice of telling their works committees about their pros- pective contracts, etc., and in some cases report considerable keenness on the part of their commit- tees in discussing them. There was during the war a very striking experiment of real workers' control in this and in every field at a Newcastle aircraft factory — John Dawson and Co., Ltd. A joint body representing management and workers exercised almost the full powers of an ordinary board of directors. *'The business of the Works Council," says the pamphlet edited by its secretary and published in March, 1919 under the title of Democratic Control the Key to Industrial Pro- gress, *'is to control matters of policy, consider and decide upon extension or contraction of busi- ness, and to provide for the maintenance of output. 232 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL The Workers' Representatives are elected by bal- lot, and have an equal voice with the Management Representatives in all decisions. There being no casting vote it is essential that both sides agree by a majority upon any question that may arise. In the absence of an agreement the subject would remain in abeyance until a common ground of action could be arrived at ... . Broadly speak- ing, the functions of the Works Council may be defined as those of a Management Council which issues its decisions to the Executive Staff for that Staif to carry into effect. The decisions of the Works Council on matters of policy are of necessity subject in all cases to the control of the Directors in regard to finance . . . The Directors have the responsibility of con- trolling the finance and sales organization of the Company, and the general work of the Staff. Whilst they are unfettered in regard to the exer- cise of their powers, the Works Council may call for, and in fact receives, all information in regard to the policy of the management, expansion of business and results of operations undertaken." The exclusion of the Works Council from financial control was explained by Mr. G. H. Humphrey, the Proprietor and originator of the scheme, as a matter of banking accommodation : — "Dependent as we are on loans and the Banks, we have to maintain a Capitalist front to the world and a TRADE POLICY: JOINT ACTION 233 Democratic one to the workers. As we are financed by loans we have to give personal guarantees, and our per- sonal guarantees have no weight unless we own half the organization, I have, therefore, given away only one half of the voting stock of the Company, retaining the other half which I use as my ballast for my personal guarantees." I This must of course be understood as one man*s experiment, and not as an illustration of a large body of experience, and it is an experiment that is no longer in operation, since John Dawson's, though highly successful in war-time production, was unable to finance the readjustment to peace conditions. It is, however, of great interest as marking the most definite devolution of an em- ployer's authority. Of almost equal interest, and perhaps of greater importance, was the -joint action on trade policy that was a by-product of State control during the war. It is true that trade union and employers' association representation on bodies charged with public functions was not quite unknown before the war; there was a minority of two labor members, for example, on the Port of London Authority. State action for war purposes made the practice of real importance. The State took over, in vari- ous degrees, the control over the most important industries in the country; in certain industries, this control was largely administered — after early 234 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL attempts to do everything by State action — • through bodies composed in part of representa- tives of employers and employed. This principle, it is true, did not extend to shipping ; the National Maritime Board was a joint body, but its func- tions were merely conciliatory. The railways were and are administered under the Board of Trade" by a Railway Executive Committee of railway presidents. The National Union of Railwaymen asked repeatedly for representation on this com- mittee; the request was denied, but the following clause was inserted in the 1919 agreement : — "When the new Ministry of Ways and Communica- tions is set up it is the intention of the Government to provide in the organization for and to avail itself fully of the advantage of assistance, co-operation, and advice from the workers in the transportation industry." Negotiations on this point are now (November, 1919) proceeding between the Government and the Railwaymen. Mr. J. H. Thomas announced at Bristol on November 16 that the Government had made an offer to the unions of three seats on the Railway Executive Committee. In the other branches of the transport industry, road transport was administered without labor representation ; but local consultative committees, on which the Transport "Workers ' Federation was represented, exercised certain functions in refer- TRADE POLICY: JOINT ACTION 235 ence to both dock and canal traffic. The coal in- dustry was much under State supervision from the outbreak of the war; by February, 1917, the Government had assumed complete control. At that time the Coal Mining Organization Committee, which included representatives of the Miners (Smillie, Hartshorn, and Walsh) and the mine- owners, and which had played an important part not only in conducting output campaigns but in suggesting economies of distribution was made into an Advisory Board to the Coal Controller, with equal representation from the two sides. The Miners ' Federation was not satisfied with the limited and purely advisory powers of this Board, and at its 1918 Conference passed the following resolution :— "In the opinion of this Conference the present form, of Governmental control of the mines tends to develop into pure bureaucratic administration, which is in itself as equally inimical to the interests of the workmen and the industry as was the uncontrolled form of private ownership. We, therefore, propose that, pending the complete nationalization of the mines with joint control by the State and the workers, the present Joint Ad- visory Committee of the Coal Controller should be vested with directive power jointly with the Coal Controller." In South Wales a Joint Allocation Committee was set up to meet the problem of distributing or- ders for the various grades of coal to the different 236 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL collieries in order to bring about uniformity of em- ployment throughout the coalfield. Mr. Hodges described this as "a taste of effective control in the allocation of trade," though Mr. Evan Wil- liams of the coal-owners insisted that while, **you gave us valuable information," the scheme itself * * was not put into operation. ' ' ' In the engineering and allied industries and particularly the production of munitions, the con- trol exercised by the State was perhaps most direct and there was very little devolution of authority (except to the Munitions Tribunals already men- tioned). In certain districts, however, notably the Northeast Coast and the Clyde, local Munitions of War Committees were set up with seven employ- ers, seven union representatives and a number of State nominees. These were directly charged with the function of accelerating production. Mr. Cole wrote * of this as a step of great importance : — "It will go down to history as tlie first definite and official recognition of the right of the workers to a say in the management of their own industries. Here for the first time the nominees of the workers meet those of the masters on equal terms, to discuss not merely wages, hours,, or conditions of labor, but the actual business of production. ' ' The real control exercised by these committees, however, varied widely with the degree of interest • Coal Commission Evidence, Questions 23705-23714. * Labor in War Time, p, 198. TRADE POLICY: JOINT ACTION 237 shown by the workers in the different locali- ties. The most striking examples of joint administra- tion by employers and employed were the Wool and Cotton Control Boards. The Government was the chief consumer of wool during the war. Early in 1916 it took considerable power under the Defence of the Realm Act to direct production, and in the same year bought almost the entire supply of raw material in order to establish priorities for war work. In April, 1917, an Advisory Com- mittee, on which the unions had five members as against twenty-four representing the employers and merchants, was set up and iromediately ex- tended the system of priorities and drastically re- stricted the hours to be worked by mills employed in the civilian trade. During August and Septem- ber, after considerable unrest in the industry, the Wool Control Board — eleven representatives of the unions, eleven of the employers, and eleven of the War Office Contracts Department — was set up with extensive powers in organizing the civilian trade and full power to ration raw material to the various branches of the industry and to the particular firms engaged. ''Clearly," says the Labor Year Book (1919), "the principle of equal representation of Trade Unions with the employers on a body possessing such powers creates a precedent of the greatest possible impor- 238 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL tance, and one which is still strongly resented by some employers in the industry." The Cotton Control Board — ^which in its final form consisted of seven employers and merchants, seven union leaders, and two nominees of the Board of Trade — exercised even more important administrative powers. The problem in the case of cotton was the shortage of raw material ; many of the ships that had formerly brought cotton were either sunk or diverted to other purposes. The object of control was to regulate the price of the raw material and to conserve the supply. The Control Board was set up on June 28, 1917; its first acts were to regulate purchases by a system of licenses and to take a complete census of cotton stocks. It was soon given full powers to fix the price of the raw material and to allocate it among the different firms. The latter function was per- formed by restricting the percentage of spindles that could be run on other than Government work. An important extension of the Board's duties resulted from the effects of the shortage and the consequent restriction. Some provision had to be made for those unemployed. The arrangement made was this : firms were to be allowed to exceed the specified percentage of spindles on payment of a levy for all spindles in excess ; this levy be- came an unemployment fund which was admin- istered, on agreed principles, wholly by the trade TRADE POLICY: JOINT ACTION 239 unions. This was discussed in Section IV as an ap- plication of the principle that unemployment should be a charge on the industry and as a definite delegation of responsibility to the trade unions for administering benefit. The case of the Cotton Control Board has been taken — by Mr. Penty, for example, in his Indus- trial Crisis and the Way Out — as a striking in- stance of trade union direction of industry. It is easy to make out the case. Here were a group of union leaders on a Board which was charged with the responsibility of meeting the problems of a great industry in a great emergency and which was given almost unlimited powers to say what work should or should not be done and what ma- chines should or should not be kept running. These were great and executive powers — certainly an opportunity for positive control. The best evi- dence, however, seems to be that, except as regards the unemployment benefit which they administered independently and with little friction, the control exercised by the union leaders was more negative than positive. They were there to see that no harm was done to the unions; the constructive planning was left almost entirely to a few of the employers and civil servants. This was not be- cause the union leaders, being in a minority, were voted down; it was because they attended only the formal weekly meetings — the real planning 240 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL was done between them. It is true that the employ- ers at the end of the war hastened to secure the abolition of the board for fear the union leaders would through it learn to run the industry ; there is no evidence, however, that they even thought of taking their position as an opportunity for learn- ing control. Joint action for commercial purposes is then not unheard of. The Whitley proposals are of some importance in offering a possibility of widen- ing the range of subjects. Joint acceptance of public responsibility for the conduct of industry was a significant war development. The next sec- tion will discuss the few trade union attempts at independent action in these fields. xvin TRADE POLICY: WORKERS' DEMANDS The previous section dealt with joint action on trade policy — action rarely initiated from the labor side and carried on for joint purposes. The pres- ent section deals with attempts by the workers to manipulate trade policy for their own purposes, with their independent suggestions for improve- ment in trade policy, and with their demands for trade and financial information. The actual in- stances are less frequent ; the fact that the initia- tive comes from the workers, however, makes them of interest for a study of control. The last section discussed the ** Birmingham Alliances," a rare instance of trade unions join- ing with their employers to rig prices. There are also rare instances of trade unions trying to rig prices on their own account by limitation of output, or of trade unions disagreeing with their employers as to the best means of rigging prices. The classic illustration of the latter is the cotton dispute of 1878 described by the Webbs. The own?- ers announced a ten per cent reduction of wages to meet a depression due to a glut in the market. The unions argued that the way to meet a glut in 241 242 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL the market was to stop overproduction, and of- fered to accept tlie reduction in wages on condition that the factories should work only four days a week. * ' One hundred thousand factory workers, ' * said the Weavers' Manifesto, "are waging war with their employers as to the best possible way to remove the glut from an overstocked market, and at the same time reduce the difficulties arising from an insufficient supply of raw cotton. To remedy this state of things the employers propose a reduction of wages. . . . We contend that a re- duction in the rate of wages cannot either remove the glut in the cloth market or assist to tide us over the difficulty arising from the limited supply of raw material. ' ' The ten weeks ' strike over eco- nomic policy finally ended in the complete defeat of the workers. The cotton unions have on this and other oc- casions clainied, unsuccessfully, a right to force upon the employers their notions of the way to adjust output to demand in order to maintain prices and wages. The Miners alone have once or twice attempted to do the adjusting on their own account. Two facts may partly explain this. For a long period of years the coal-owners in certain districts, notably Northumberland, had agreed to a limitation of output — ''the limitation of the vend" — for the purpose of keeping up the price of coal; of this the workers were, of course, aware TRADE POLICY: WORKERS' DEMANDS 243 and in Lancashire had even been at times parties to the agreement. In the second place, the miners' wages in many districts were governed, either under formal sliding scale agreement or according to the general practice of arbitrators, by the sel- ling price of coal ; manipulation of the selling price by the owners or dealers was thus felt by the min- ers to be ''gambling with men's wages." It is not then surprising that the Miners have in a few instances insisted that, "supply and demand should be adjusted rather by diminishing the out- put than by forcing coal upon unwilling buyers." In 1892 the Miners saved themselves from a reduc- tion in wages, threatened on account of the great surplus stocks of coaP which the coal-owners could not sell, by arbitrarily taking a week's holi- day. A similar issue arose just before the out- break of war in 1914. The Scottish Miners were threatened with a reduction which would have brought their wages below the national minimum agreed on by the Miners' Federation; yet they were under agreement to submit to arbitration, and the lowered price of coal, due to overproduc- tion, would be used as the chief argument against them. The Scottish union, apparently following an expedient sometimes practiced in Lanarkshire, decided to work only four days a week in order to * It Is very difiScult in 1919 to think back to a time when there could have oeen " great surplus stocks of coal " in England. ^44 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL reduce the surplus and to force up the price. The matter was vigorously debated at a conference of the Miners' Federation of Great Britain. /'When they were last before the neutral chairman, ' ' said a Scottish delegate, "one of the grounds put for- ward for the reduction of 25% was that some of the collieries were only working two or three days a week, and because of the glut of coal in the market prices were going down. The four-days policy would enable all their men to get an equal share of work, and would also take in hand the insane competition amongst the sellers of coal." The question was argued at length. For the policy it was urged that: — "If the employers will not so regulate the working of the mines as to prevent the overproduction and bring wages up to a decent living wage, then the workers themselves are entitled to take the matters into their own hands." On the other hand there was a strong feeling against "the acceptance of the principle of the policy of restriction." The Conference finally decided not to approve the four-days policy, but to support the Scottish Miners in case their wages fell below the agreed minimum. Within two weeks the Great War had broken out; and in the "in- dustrial truce" that followed immediately, and with the increased demand for coal which was a TRADE POLICY: WORKERS' DEMANDS 245 more lasting effect of the war, the issue was not pressed. These direct attempts to regulate the amount of production for the sake of wages are unusual even in the two industries named and practically unknown outside. There are, however, cases of suggestions for changes in trade policy less im- mediately connected with wages. The Miners' demand that ^* small coal" should be brought to the surface and used and paid for is perhaps a border case. The demand begins with wages; it is supported by arguments of the danger of ''gob fires ' ' when the coal is stowed in the workings and of the national waste involved. The 1916 Confer- ence resolved: — "That the Miners' Federation of Great Britain be urged to take immediate steps to bring before the Coal Control Board the enormous national loss caused by the practice of stowing small coal in the workings, with a view of making the necessary arrangements for secur- ing that all coal produced in the mines should be sent to the surface." A long-standing argument of the Miners for na- tionalization that on the ground of conservation, is clearly a demand for an improvement in the policy of the industry: — "Unless we press for the nationalization of mines at once there will be nothing but the worst seams left for the nation to work." 246 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL A very large part of the Miners' case before the Coal Commission was taken up with the argument on technical grounds that unification by national- ization would make possible a number of improve- ments^—the pooling of privately-owned railway trucks, for example — in trade policy. The most conspicuous instance of a trade union suggesting schemes for the improvement of its industry is that of the Postal and Telegraph Clerks' Association. Some years ago its parent society (United Kingdom Postal Clerks' Associa- tion) printed a pamphlet containing a scheme for extending the service by the institution of a postal banking scheme. Its foreword read : — "With a view to bringing before the public the pos- sibilities of the British Postal Service as a means of pro- viding the business community and the general public with the facilities for the transaction of business, the United Kingdom Postal Clerks' Association has been tabulating evidence and information concerning the Postal Services of other countries. This pamphlet outlines the most remarkable feature of Post Office activity which has taken place during the last five years, viz., the development of the Post Office Bank- ing Business for the transmission of moneys, known as the Postal Cheque and Transfer Service. The importance of the subject from a business stand- " These suggestions are listed in two of the first set of reports issued by the Coal Commission — that of Justice Sankey and three employers and that of the six labor representatives. Cmd. 87 and 85. TRADE POLICY: WORKERS' DEMANDS 247 point has impelled the Postal Clerks* Association to place this matter before the public with a view to direct- ing attention to Postal affairs, so that the Post Office Authorities may be induced to improve and develop the Service on the lines indicated." With either the details or the merits of the pro- ject, this inquiry is, of course, not concerned; the point is that it represents the expenditure of trade union money and energy in attempting to force what is believed to be an improvement of the ser- vice in which its members are engaged. Appar- ently this intention is still of importance to the Postal and Telegraph Clerks. A resolution passed at their 1916 Conference declared : — "This Conference is convinced that . . . the most effective work which the Executive Committee can ac- complish during the period immediately before us will 'be by applying itself to consideration of the problem of development of the Service, having in mind the needs of the community, the possibility of increased services to the community ..." and the betterment of condi- tions for the staff. Another resolution passed at the same Confer- ence shows the direct bearing of this sort of inter- est in industry on the problem of control : — "Having in view the possibility of the Association as- suming in the future more direct and active participa- 248 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL tion in the administration of the Postal Service, this Conference recommends the organization within the branches of circles for 'craft' study and discussion. Members of the Association only to be admitted to such circles. ' ' ■ The Branch moving the resolution had already started such a study group. Similarly the Execu- tive Committee urged the rank and file to educate themselves to apply the Whitley report and in turn to use the Whitley scheme as an education in control : ^ — ** Members should begin to study minutely the con- ditions of their offices and the history of trade and in- dustry, so that when the time comes they are prepared to administer the principle with a statesmanship worthy of a great trade union." In more than one union the preaching of the study of the industry as a step toward control has been part of recent propaganda by the leaders.* The fear of just this was a reason for the employ- ers' objection to the Cotton Control Board already referred to — the fear that the union leaders would learn too much about finance,^ perhaps by hearing • In a speech condemning the Whitley report as oflFering no real workers' control, I heard one of the ablest of the younger advocates of control taking this attitude toward the labor sym- pathizers on the Whitley committee: — don't blame them; they were trying to provide a training ground. * One' of thera declared, however that, " you might as well talk to wooden dummies." ' The cotton union secretaries had long had the reputation of knowing a great deal about the financial position of their industry. TRADE POLICY: WORKERS' DEMANDS 249 the merchants and manufacturers accuse each other of profiteering. The labor side of the Wool Control Board was more conscious of this pos- sibility, and several of the leaders regret bitterly the chance lost by not putting a representative on the full-time staff of the Board. This desire for a general knowledge of the work- ings of industry and finance with a direct eye to learning control is confined to a very few. The demand for publicity of profits is a widespread one. Oh yes, said a trade union leader to me, the employers will discuss anything with us '' except perhaps costing amd profits.'^ Here is another keenly-felt frontier of control. It was touched on by a Scottish miner in the debate on the Miners' Four Days in 1914: — "If any such increase in the cost of production has taken place, they [the employers] will have to open their books and prove it, and further, we want to know what profits have been during these periods on the price ob- tained. They say they will never open their books to us and show their profits, as in their opinion we have nothing to do with profits ; that is a question for them. ' ' By 1919 the coal-owners were in fact opening their books to show their profits to the Coal Com- mission. D. F. Schloss quoted one of them as follows j — ^''We know . . the j!;eneral rate of profits, depreciation, costs, etc., . . , and we know that after we have got our wages out of it, and we leave the balance to the employer, he has nothing to make a great noise about." 250 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL It is hard to overestimate the importance of the ComLmission in this connection, first, because of the actual profits revealed, second, because of the Commission's practically unanimous recommenda- tion in favor of future publicity of profits, and third, because of its effect in encouraging a similar demand in other trades. The first result is of no concern for the present inquiry. The second is of importance and has been given comparatively little public attention for the very reason that it was an agreed recommendation. The Chairman's report and Sir Arthur Duckham's are on this mat- ter identical in substance. The latter reads as follows : — "It is essential that there should be complete pub- licity as to the operations and financial results of the coal industry. The Ministry of Mines should be ex- pressly charged with the duty of publishing, not less than once a year, figures showing the cost of getting coal in each of the districts of the country, and the propor- tion chargeable to materials, wages, general expenses, interest, profits, and other general items. ' ' The other five employers do not touch definitely upon this point in their recommendations, but they quote with evident approval the even more em- phatic opinion expressed in the evidence and scheme submitted by the Mining Association of Great Britain: — TRADE POLICY: WORKERS' DEMANDS 251 ''The authors [of the coal-owners' project] contend that want of knowledge with respect to prices, costs and profits, and the absence of machinery conferring upon the workers opportunities for obtaining information and influencing the conditions under which they work have been to a great extent the cause of the existing discon- tent. The authors propose th^t, in future, fluctuations of the wages of the workers in each mining district, over and above the minimum rates, should, instead of being regulated solely as in the past by selling prices, be regu- lated by reference also to costs and profits in that dis- trict. For this purpose, average prices, costs and profits in each district are to he jointly ascertained, so that the workers may he able in future to discuss questions of wages with a complete knowledge of the results of the industry in that district." (Italics mine.) On the third point — ^the influence which the great publicity of the Commission's work has had in encouraging similar demands in other industries it is too early to gather much evidence. One ex- pression of it, from a prominent building trades official, was something like this : — we '11 never again accept the plea that they can't afford an advance until they show us the books ! These trade union demands on the subject of trade policy are neither many nor of frequent oc- currence, but the range they cover is significantly wide. In a few cases the unions have tried to alter 252 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL their employers' trade policy in adjusting output to demand. In others they have suggested specific improvements in trade policy. And finally they have made some claim to be shown the inner workings of the business direction of industry. XIX THE EXTENT OF CONTROL The attempt has been made in the preceding sec- tions to indicate the specific sorts of control of in- dustry now exercised by organized workers in Great Britain. I know no way of adding these and making a neat sum. How much control have the workers got? There is no use in making gen- eral answers, like ''very little" or "a good deal." But in weighing and judging the extent of control, certain distinctions which have been implicit in the previous discussion are worth making explicit. '' Agreeable control is better than enforced con- trol," I heard a Birmingham toolmaker say. "In- vasion, not admission, should be the trade union- ist's watchword," said one of the prominent Guild Socialists. The distinction is of some importance. Which is better depends on what you want, and on economy of effort in getting it ; but, from the point of view of definition, enforced control is control in a more real sense. There is a significant psycho- logical difference between "admission" and "in- vasion, ' ' between control presented to and control seized by a trade union. The distinction may be 263 254. THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL made clearer by illustration. When ** Bedstead Smith" organized the first of the ''Birmingham Alliances ' ' and let the trade unions come in on the deal, the sort of workers' ''control" over price- fixing that resulted was a very different thing from the sort of control that would have resulted, say, if the "Miners' Four Days" policy in 1914 had been applied and had raised the price of coal. Control implies initiative; for that reason, forms of control entirely initiated from above must be ruled out unless or until they are shown to involve workers ' activity as well as acquiescence. On that ground co-partnership and similar bits of "con- trol" offered to workers in connection with profit- sharing schemes have been left out of consider- ation. This same distinction accounts for the paradox of a refusal of control pointed out with such surprise in the chairman's statement of the Ebbw Vale Steel, Iron, and Coal Co. (July 2, 1919) :— "After very mature consideration your directors de- cided to extend an invitation to one of the great trade unions to nominate one of their number to occupy a seat on this board. We felt that the presence of a rep- resentative of labor on this board, with all the privileges, with all the responsibilities of an ordinary director, would perhaps give him the opportunity of realizing the many difficulties which from time to time confront those men whose duty it is to control the destinies of our great THE EXTENT OF CONTROL 255 industrial campanies. We felt that in realizing and ap- preciating our difficulties lie might possibly be able to take a broader view of the many questions which have from time to time to be settled between capital and labor; we felt that the presence of a representative of labor on this board would have given an opportunity to myself and to my colleagues to have learned the views of labor at first hand. "I regret to say our invitation to labor has been re- fused. In that I am somewhat surprised and consid- erably disappointed. If labor seeks to control industry, then labor should be prepared to serve its apprenticeship side by side with men who have made it their lifelong study." Eeal control of industry cannot be presented like a Christmas-box. Certain of the advocates of ''control" push this distinction even to the point of saying that joint control cannot be in any sense workers' control. Mr. J. T. Murphy, the spokesman of the Shop Stewards' Movement, publishes an attack on the Whitley proposals with the significant title, ''Compromise or Independence," in which he says that: — "A 'joint' committee can only be a committee of em- ployers and employees formed to prevent any encroach- ment on the power of the dominant body, in this case the employers." But this is surely an overstatement. The Build- ing Trades Council's committee on "Organized 256 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL Public Service" hardly fits Mr. Murphy's defini- tion; and it is impossible to imagine Mr. Smillie, for example, losing his independence by sitting on a joint body like the Coal Mining Organization Committee. It is impossible to rule out all forms of joint control; the test must be whether in the particular instance of joint control the workers' side is independently active. Joint control when the lead is entirely from the employing side — as in co-partnership and the "Birmingham Alli- ances"— may be disregarded. But the Whitley Councils must be studied and judged by their ac- tions; the classification of each council depends not on its constitution but on the purely empirical question whether the chief function of the workers ' side is to be that of junior partnership in petition- ing for Protection and similar favors from the Government or whether, as is already the case in the Building Trades Council, the workers' side is to play an active part in shaping policy. ''One point, however, must be made clear," says Mr. Malcolm Sparkes, the chief founder of that council, in an article maintaining that the Industrial Coun- cil Movement is going in the same direction as the Shop Stewards ' Movement. •' ' In itself the Indus- trial Council is no solution for the problem of con- trol. It is, however, an instrument that can pro- duce the solution." The same test of actual in- dependence of function applies also to joint bodies THE EXTENT OF CONTROL 257 exercising state-given powers. This was the basis of the questions asked in Section XVII about the Cotton Control Board. So with the various schemes of voluntary '^devolution of managerial functions. " The initiative here is clearly from the top. Mr. Humphrey of John Dawson's makes the distinction in the pamphlet already cited : — "There is a likelihood of a great educative movement amongst the working classes as a result of which they will take a large measure of control, and their obstruc- tive employers will wish they had given joint control in their own works when they had the chance to do it gracefully. ' ' Until such schemes are actively taken up by the workers, they amount to nothing in the way of control, however much they cover on paper. But when or if they are so taken up, they should not be ruled out because of their origin; what begins as a gift may become a right. The line between "agreeable" and ''enforced" control, or better be- tween dependent and mdependent control, must be drawn not on the ground of the origin of con- trol or even of the extent of control, but solely by the test of whether or not the workers' side does actually exert an independent force. A similar distinction, and one more frequently drawn, is that between negative and positive con- 258 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL trol. It is a commonplace that the control now exercised by the workers is mainly negative — that they may sometimes say *'no," or say that work must not be done, or changes must not be intro- duced, except under certain conditions, but they can very rarely say that this or that must be done. They are in the position, as Mr. Tawney says, of ''an Opposition that never becomes a Govern- ment." It is easy to confirm this from the in- stances given; most of the ''trade union con- ditions"— of hiring, apprenticeship, demarcation, and the rest — are clearly negative. It is much shorter to enumerate the instances of positive con- trol. In the staffing of shops and in the selection of foremen, the Stuff Pressers exercise positive choice. There are other cases of independent ad- ministration by the workers within sharply limited fields, for example by the printers' "clicker" in allocating work and by the miners ' safety inspec- tors. The workmen directors at Dawson's were charged with positive functions; certain shop stewards actually — though not in name — exercised directive powers during the war. And finally there are the "Insistences on Changes in Technique" by the Miners' output committees and others, which were emphasized because of the great cur- rent significance of this distinction. Positive con- trol covers then only a very small proportion of the cases even of that independent control defined THE EXTENT OF CONTROL 259 in the preceding paragraph. On the other hand, a number of the newer demands are put forward with just this sort of control in mind. The Clyde committee, whose proposals were quoted in Section XV, wanted the right to say not under what con- ditions machinery might be introdileed but actually where it should be introduced. The object of the scheme of collective contract put forward is to ' * take over a whole province ' ' of industrial direc- tion from the employers. In fact the essence of the new demand of labor, as was stated by Mr. Henry Clay in the Observer, is for ''participation in the direction and not merely in the regulation of industry." Insistence on this distinction* does not imply that regulation and negative control are not real control or that they are not of great im- portance. The standard of foremanship, for ex- ample, is maintained almost entirely by the highly negative process of insurgence. And the right to say yes or no shades very easily into the right to say which or what. But the distinction is worth emphasizing, as indicating the new Frontier of Control — over which the conscious struggle is marked on the one hand by Mr. Frank Hodges' demand on behalf of the workers for ''the daily exercise of directive ability" and on the other by Lord Gainford's testimony before the Coal Com- mission : — 260 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL "I am authorized to say on behalf of the Mining Association that if owners are not to be left complete executive control they will decline to accept the respon- sibility of carrying on the industry." A third distinction — and one that I have no- where seen definitely stated — is that between what might be called old craft or customary control on the one hand and conscious or contagious control on the other. This is based not on the greater or less degree of ''reality" of control exercised but on the nature and policy of the union exercising it. It is a distinction of no importance if the ob- ject of inquiry is merely the static one of present- ing the sum of instances of control. But for any study in terms of process, for any study that pre- tends to estimate moving tendencies, it seems to me of the highest importance. The more striking instances of control already mentioned fall quite clearly into two main classes: — on the one hand control long exercised as a customary right by con- servative, exclusive, and usually small unions in old skilled crafts, fighting if at all only to resist ' ' encroachments ' ' on their ancient privileges ; and on the other hand control newly and consciously won by aggressive, propagandist, usually indus- trial, unions in the great organized industries, fighting not to resist encroachments but to make them. The Stuff Pressers, the Hand Papermakers, THE EXTENT OF CONTROL 261 the Glass Bottle Makers,^ the Calico Printers and, less typically, the Compositors are instances of the former class of unions. The Miners and the Railwaymen are the most highly-developed ex- amples of the latter. Cases of these two sorts of control, or of the first sort and of the demand for the second, have been set down side by side in almost every section: — full control over employ- ment exercised by the Stuff Pressers and full con- trol over employment demanded by certain indus- trial unionists among the Engineers; sharing of work long practised by the Yorkshire Glass Bottle Makers and rationing of employment demanded by the Clyde Engineers ; the Hand Papermakers long guaranteed ''six days' custom" and the Railway- men this year securing a guaranteed weekly wage ; the Stuff Pressers choosing their own foremen and the activists among Engineers, Miners, Railway- men, and Postal Workers pushing for the right; Compositors and Miners alike enforcing a stand- ard of foremanship and preventing ** policing"; the printers' clicker allocating work by long cus- tom and certain Tramwaymen securing it as a new right; co-operative work in the Cornish tin mines and collective contract a new demand of Glasgow engineers; and so on. The difference then is not primarily in the actual bits of control exercised, nor is it merely a matter of the date * See above, p. 168. . . • 262 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL of acquisition of power. If the latter difference did not carry with it a totally different attitude of mind and if, for example, an official of the Stuff Pressers toured the country with Mr. Frank Hodges of the Miners and seconded the latter 's speeches on behalf of *' Workers' Control" by stating that his union had had some workers ' con- trol and had found it good, the distinction might very well be ignored. But in point of fact, nothing like this does or could happen. In the first place, the old crafts have no theories of the value of con- trol for control's sake. Just for this reason the Stuff Pressers are giving up their right to elect foremen almost without protest, since the change is going on with no immediate practical loss. Similarly the old crafts are thoroughly conserva- tive; they are engaged in defending "established expectations" ^ just as definitely as the advocates * The old craft type of mind is best described on p. 671 of Industrial Democracy : — " The Doctrine of Vested Interests. . . . is naturally strongest in the remnants of the time-honored ancient handicrafts. Those who have troubled to explore the nooks and crannies of the industrial world, which have hitherto escaped the full intensity of the commercial struggle, will have found in them a peculiar type of Trade Union character. Wherever the Doc- trine of Vested Interests is still maintained by the workmen, and admitted by the employers — where, that is to say, the conditions of employment are consciously based, not on the competitive battle but on the established expectations of the different classes — we find an unusual prevalence, among the rank and file, of what we may call the 'gentle' nature — that conjunction of quiet dig- nity, grave courtesy, and consideration of other people's rights and feelings, which is usually connected with old family and long- established position. But this type of character becomes every day rarer in the Trade Union world." No contract could be sharper than that between this " gentleness " and the aggressive- THE EXTENT OF CONTROL 263 of the newer control are in the broad sense revolu- tionary and out to attack ''established expecta- tions. ' ' The father of a compositors ' chapel talks of the London * ' Scale ' ' with much the same rever- ence that a thoroughgoing engineers ' shop steward saves for the Social Revolution. And as a natural corollary, the old crafts are exclusive and aristo- cratic and play little part in the labor movement ; the advocates of the newer control are widely propagandist. The Stuff Pressers keep themselves to themselves and hug their monopoly ; the authors of the Miners' Next Step are propagandists for control on the expressed ground that :— * * We cannot get rid of employers and slave-driving in the mining industry, until all other industries have organized for and progressed towards the same objec- tive. Their rate of progress conditions ours ; all we can do is to set an example and the pace. ' * This difference in intention clearly makes a difference in results. Nobody supposes that the Railwaymen demanded a guaranteed week because the Hand Papermakers had one ; on the other hand, ness of the modern advocate of the Doctrine of Workers' Control. The latter temper at its extreme may be indicated by a few sen- tences from one of J. T. Murphy's pamphlets: — "They [the em- ployers] struggled through the centuries to obtain their power. We also of the working-class have come through the long years of strife and have suffered their batterings and their spite. We do not squeal. Struggle is the law of life. As we see they rose on the backs of our class we see and feel now the gathering power of the labor hosts." 264 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL the publicity of profits which the Miners secured through the Coal Conunission almost immediately becomes a demand in other trades. This distinc- tion is of great importance in estimating the po- tential significance of these forms of workers ' con- trol. Old craft control is traditional and clings on but does not spread. On the other hand, news of each ''invasion" made by the theorists and propa- gandists of the newer control is carried to other trades and made the basis of agitation there. It is for this reason that the word ''contagious" seems a significant one for describing this newer and more conscious control. The two things are not the same: — old craft control almost neces- sarily implies small groups of skilled workers ; the advocates of contagious control are for the most part either members of industrial unions or strong advocates of industrial unionism; the temper of the old crafts is monopolistic and conservative; that of the latter, propagandist and revolutionary. Undoubtedly there is some slight degree of cross- influence, just as the various attempts at inde- pendent associations of producers have no doubt had some influence on the present and very differ- ent demand for control. The printing unions are by no means isolated from the general tendencies of the labor movement,^ and of course there are • The printing unions were among the first to oiFer their help to the Railwaymen during the recent strilce. THE EXTENT OF CONTROL 265 many unions of various sorts between the two extreme types indicated here. But the types are widely and fundamentally different, and it seems to me almost futile to argue from the experience of one to the other: — equally futile, for example, to argue that direct election of foremen would be a good thing for all industry because it worked for a long time with the Stuff Pressers, or to argue that the right to elect foremen is proved of no use to other workmen because the Stuff Pressers are giving it up without protest. And for the purpose of attempting to forecast future develop- ments, the distinction is of the highest importance. It raises the entire question of the historical rela- tion between the type of industrial technique and the type of industrial government. You cannot base a theory of modern industry on the tin mines of Cornwall. Old craft control is a survival from an earlier technology and is clearly dying out with the industrial conditions that made it possible. Contagious control is a demand made in view of the newer industrial technique ; the judgment as to whether or not it is to grow must be made in- dependently of the decay of the other. The answer to the question, How much controls depends, then, on whether or not the question it- self is qualified in any of the three senses indicated above. If it is not qualified, the nearest answer 266 THE FRONTIER OF CONTROL that can be given is : — all the control indicated in the earlier sections and whatever more may be thought of under co-partnership or other devices of ''industrial peace." K the question is how much independent control? — and this seems to me the broadest sense in which the term ''control'* can be used with any significance — the few cases mentioned in which the initiative lies entirely with the employers must be ruled out, and all instances of joint control must be narrowly examined to see whether they involve workers' activity or merely workers' acquiescence. If the question is how much positive control? — and this question is of importance as marking the newest Frontier of Control — the answer can be given in a very few instances, — of which the staffing of shops and choice of foremen by the Stuff Pressers, the work of the labor-directors at Dawson's, and the in- sistences by a few Miners' output committees on specific improvements in management, are the most conspicuous. If the question is how much contagious control? — and this question is import- ant for any guesses about the future — ^nearly half the cases mentioned, including some of the more striking forms of positive control and the greater part of the negative control covered by the phrase "the right to a trade," must be ruled out as hav- ing little bearing on the moving tendencies in the great industry. NOTE ON SOURCES The following is a brief list of the more valuable sources of material on workers' control — of those, that is, that can be obtained outside the Labour Research Department or Scotland Yard. I. BRITISH GOVERNMENT PUBLICATIONS. (H. M. Stationery Office, Imperial Hoiise, Kingsway, London W. C. 2.) Report on Collective Agreements. 1910, Cd. 5,366. The most comprehensive cross-section picture of the extent and variety of trade union agreements. Annual Reports on Strikes and Lockouts. 1910, Cd. 5,850. •1911, Cd. 6,472. 1912, Cd. 7,089. 1913, Cd. 7,658. A valuable indication of the magnitude and, less ac- curately, the causes of strikes. The sections on the specific issues of strikes are especially suggestive. The classifica- tion of causes is, however, inconvenient for the purposes of the student of control. Report of the Commissioners on Industrial Unrest. 1917. The section on South Wales discusses the demand for control. Works Committees. Ministry of Labour. Industrial Report No. 2. (Reprinted in America by the Bureau of Industrial Research, New York.) The most useful single official document on workers' control. Ably written and packed' with invaluable factual material. Further material is being collected for a second edition. The Whitley Report. Ministry of Labour. Industrial Re- port No. 1. Industrial Councils. Ministry of Labour. Industrial Report No. 4. Sample provisions from the constitutions of Whitley Councils. Recommendations of the Provisional Joint Committee of the Industrial Conference. 1919, Cmd. 139. A somewhat startling indication of the things on which British employers and workers agree. 267 268 NOTES Coal Industry Commission. Interim Reports. 1919, Cmd. 84, 85, 86. Coal Industry Commission. Reports of Second Stage. 1919, Cmd. 210. The famous " Sankey Report " recommending nation- alization of the mines with a considerable measure of workers' control. Coal Industry Commission. Minutes of Evidence. Cmd. 359, 360. The record of a great public clinic in the economics and psychology of modern industry. Control is a leading theme throughout. A great mine of valuable material on this and other subjects that has not yet been worked over by students. II. SOURCE MATERIALS ON WORKERS' CONTROL. A. The Peopaganda of " Complete Contbol. " The Miners' Next Step. Unofficial Reform Committee. Tonypandy, South Wales. 1912. Industrial Democracy for Miners. A Plan for the Demo- cratic Control of the Mining Industry. The Industrial Committee of the South Wales Socialist Society, Forth, Rhondda Valley, South Wales, 1919. The contrast between these two pamphlets, the work of the same group of rank-and-file extremists, is a striking indication of the increasing hopefulness with which the claim for control is urged. The Miners' Next Step is bitter and purely destructive, advocating the irritation strike, and is still publicly referred to with bated breath as the type of all that is criminal in syndicalism. Its sequel is hopeful and entirely con- cerned with constructive, though equally " impossi- bilist," plans of organizing control. J. T. Murphy. The Workers' Committee. Sheffield Workers' Committee, 56 Rushdale Road, Meersbrook, Sheffield. 1918. By the chief spokesman for the Shop Stewards Move- ment. Claimed a sale of 30,000 copies up to May, 1919. J. T. Murphy. Compromise or Independence? An Ex- animation of the Whitley Report. Sheffield Workers' Committee. W. Gallecher and J. Paton. Towards Industrial De- mocrccj/; A Mem,ora/ndum on Workshop Control. Trades and Labour Coimcil, Paisley, Scotland. 1917. A scheme of " collective contract " devised by two of the Clyde shop stewards. Taken up in the propaganda of the National Guild League. NOTES 269 B. The Miners' Case fob Contbol. R. Page Arnot. Facts from the Coal Commission and Further Facts from the Coal Commission. Miners' Federation, Russell Square, London. 1919. A skillful abridgement of the most telling evidence for the Miners' case. The second pamphlet contains the text of the Miners' Bill for Nationalization. Frank Hodges. The Nationalisation of the Mines. Par- sons. London. 1920. By the Secretary of the Miners' Federation, who of all prominent labor leaders has most consistently thought of himself as a student of the control problem. C. " Joint Control " in the Building Trades. Organized Public Service in the Building Industry. The Industrial Council for the Building Industry. 48 Bed- ford Square, London. 1919. The far-reaching " Foster Report " presented by a sub-committee of the Buildijig Trades Parliament. Thos. Foster. Masters cmd Men. Headley. London. Mr. Foster is a prominent building trades employer, a Guild Socialist, and chairmtui of the committee that drafted the " Foster Report." History of the Building Trades Parliament. Garton Foundation. London. 1919. First-hand. Somewhat sentimental. D. Employers' Experiments with Control. C. G. Renold. Workshop Committees. Suggested Lines of Development. Hans Renold, Ltd., Manchester. 1917. (Reprinted in America by the Survey.) Mr. Renold is a Cornell graduate and the managing director of a highly successful and somewhat "Ameri- canized " chain factory outside of Manchester. Democratic Control the Key to Industrial Progress. John Dawson, Ltd., Newcastle-on-Tyne. 1919. An account of the boldest attempt on the part of an employer (Mr. G. H. Humphreys) to give control to the workers. The firm flourished during the war but failed to survive the peace. E. An Engineer's Counterblast Against Control, Alex. Richardson. The Man-Power of the Nation. Reprinted from Engineering, 35 Bedford St., Strand, London. 1916. III. BOOKS ON BRITISH TRADE UNIONISM. Sidney and Beatrice Webb. History of Trade Unionism, Longmans, Green. London, New York. 1894. 270 NOTES Sidney and Beatrice Webb. Industrial Democracy. Long- mans, Green. London, New York. 1897. The two great classics of trade unionism. I have drawn heavily on their material throughout, perhaps most ob- viously in the earlier part of Section IV and in Section V. It is interesting to note, however, that their material is arranged without specific reference to the control problem. The Doctrine of Workers' Control had not yet been in- vented. / Sidney Webb. The Restoration of Trade Union Conditions. Huebsch. 1917. Sidney and Beatrice Webb. The History of Trade Unionism. Longmans, Green. London, New York. 1920. A new edition, revised and brought up to date. G. D. H. Cole. An Introdtwtion to Trade Unionism. Bell. London. 1918. The best brief statement of current trade union prob- lems. Valuable statistical appendices on trade union membership. G. D. H. Cole. Labour in War Time. Bell. London. 1915. G. D. H. Cole and R. Page Arnot. Trade Unionism on the Railways. Allen and IJnwin. London. 1917. G. D. H. Cole. The World of Labour. Bell. London. 1915. American students should not judge this by its chapter on American Labor, which is not a fair sample. G. D. H. Cole. Self-Government in Industry. Bell. London. 1917. G. D. H. Cole. Labour in the Commonwealth. Headley. London. 1919. Mr. Cole's work is almost as indispensable to the study of current trade unionism as is that of the Webbs for the earlier period. The last two books are less concerned with trade unionism as it is than with trade unionism as a Guild Socialist would like to make it, but they also contain information not accessible elsewhere. All the books are written with the control problem in the very forefront. Labour Year Book, 1916. Labour Party, 33 Eccleston Square, London. Labour Year Book, 1910. Labour Party, London. Useful catalogues of and by the labor movement. The Industrial Situation After the War. Garton Foundation. London. 1918, 1919. IV. BOOKS ON SPECIAL PROBLEMS. A. Unemployment. W. H. Beveridge. Unemployment: A Problem of In- dustry. Longmans. London. 1910. NOTES 271 R. Williams. The First Year's Working of the Liverpool Docks Scheme. London. 1914. B. Methods of Payment. D. F. Schloss. Methods of Industrial Remuneration. Williams and Newgate. London. 1892, 1894, 1898. G. D. H. Cole. The Payment of Wages. Allen and Unwin. London. 1918. V. AMERICAN BOOKS ON BRITISH LABOR. Paul U. Kellogg and Arthur Gleason. British Labor and the War. Boni and Liveright. New York. 1919. Arthur Gleason. What the Workers Want. Harcourt, Brace and Howe. New York. 1920. Mr. Gleason is by far the best informed American journalist on British Labor. The earlier book is mainly concerned with political questions, but Part VI and a number of the appendices are useful in the present con- nection. The latter book makes industry its main busi- ness and contains very valuable material. The first- hand description of the human side of the Coal Com- mission, and the statements secured from the leaders of the Miners and the Shop Stewards, are especially useful. INDEX "Abnormal places," 167 Absentee Committees, 149 Absenteeism, 209 Agreement, Bradford Dyers' Association, 68, 80, 118; Brooklands, 166; Engineer- ing Trades, 57; Leek Silk Weavers', 187; Linotype Op- erators', 188; Liverpool Dockers', 58; Oldham, 224- 225; Pottery, 58; Scottish Bookbinders', 188, Sliding Scale, 243; Steel Dressers', 61; "Treasury," 171, 194-197 Agreements, collective, 56-58 Allocation of Work, 58, 61, 155- 156, 190 Amalgamated Society of En- gineers, 21, 98-99, " Amicable discipline," 35 Apprentices, limitation of, 58 Apprenticeship, 21, 92-98, 181; Britannia Metal Smiths, rules of, 95 Authority, of Employers, 56-57 ; opposition to, 30-31 Barnes, George, 99 Barr and Stroud's, 218 Bell, Robert, 59 Beveridge, W. H., 83 Bevin, Ernest, 84 Birmingham Alliances, 241-242 Birmingham brass trades' grad- ing system, 165 Bowley, Professor, 75-76, 86 Bradford Dyers' Association Agreement, 1914, 68, 80, 118; payment system of, 172-173 Bradshaw, Secretary, on build- ing-trades labor supply, 101 " Brains Committee," 219 Bramwell, Hugh, testimony of, 106, 212-214 British Westinghouse Co., 220 Brooklands Agreement, 166 Building Trades Parliament, 8ee under Joint Industrial Council Ca'canny policy, 172, 178 Cadbury's, 218, 219 Cannan, Edwin, testimony of, 28-29 Cecil, Lord Robert, quoted, 28 Central Labor College, 5 Clay, Henry, 27, 259 Cleveland Rules, the, 148-149 Clyde Dilution Scheme, 10, 197- 201 Clyde Shop Steward's case, 32 Clyde Workers' Committee, 8, 259 Coal Commission, 1, 46, 51, cund see under Miners Coal Miners, see under Miners Cole, G. D. H., 6, 161-162, 164, 168, 236 Collective Agreements, 56-58 Collective bargaining, 53, 62, 165, 166, 168 Collective Contract payment, 173 Compulsory Unionism, 128 Conciliation Boards, 14, 224- 226 Control, " agreeable," 253 ; a political word, 36-38; "con- tagious," 266 ; " complete ex- ecutive," 51-52; demand for, 3-50; degree of^ 54-55; Derby- shire Miners and, 44; extent of, 253-266; favored by Trade Unionists, 17, 18; 273 274 INDEX Frontier of, 56-71; Guild So- cialists and, 5-6; independ- ent, 257, 266; irksomeness of present system of, 35; Marx- ian Industrial Unionists and, 5; Miners' Federation and, 12; National Union of Rail- Avaymen and, 13-14; negative, 202, 217, 257; Old Craft, 264-265; over choice of fore- men, 120 ; political factors of, 38; positive, 257, 264, 266; resentment against, 30-35 ; striking instances of, 260-261 ; State, 233; technical factors of, 39; wage element dom- inant factor in, 21; workers', 4 et seq., 56. Co-operative work, 173-175 Cotton Control Board, 237-239, 248; policy concerning im- employment, 80-81 Craftsmanship, 39-42 Dawson's, John, 231-233, 258 De-casualization Policy, 83 Defence of the Realm Act, 237 Demand for control, 1-50; or- ganized demand, 4-18; by propagandist bodies, 5-7 ; shop stewards, 7-11; trade unions, 11-18; unorganized demand, 18-50 Demarcation issue, 99-100, 181 Denny's, Wm., 218 Dilution, 100-03, 181-182, 189; Clyde scheme of, 10, 197-201 Direct Representation from Workshops, 9 Discipline and management, 61- 62 Duckham, Sir Arthur, 250 Education in control, 248 Employers, authority of, 56, 60; limitation on, 63, 77; policy relative to foremen, 129-132 Employment, 63 et seq.; joint control cf , 68 ; " rationing," 73; regularizing, 82-85; re- strictions on, 92 et seq.; imion membership a condi- tion of, 64-66 Engineering and Shipbuilding Draughtsmen, 70 Engineering Trades Agreement, 1898, 57 Factory Act regulations, 154 Fines, 210 Foremanship, standard of, 135- 145 Foremen, choice of, 117-125 National Industrial Confer ence report on, 132-133 organization of, 126-134 separate unions for, 130 workers' choice of, 120-121, 135 Foremen's Benefit Society, 131, 133 " Forty-hour Movement," 76 Foster Report, 6, 25, 86-91, 229-230 Foster, Thomas, 86 Gainford, Lord, 155, 259-260 Gallacher-Paton memorandum, 10, 70-71, 123, 174 Garton Foundation, report of, 19 Gaunt's, Reuben, 108 Glasgow Trades Union Con- gress, 15-18 Gleasdn, Arthur, 41 Guaranteed Time, 78-79, 91 Guild Socialists, 5, 122 Hamilton, Lord Claud, 59 Hodges, Frank, 12, 22, 23, 36, 164, 206-207, 212-213, 259 Humphrey, G. H., 232 Improvements, insistence on, 202-216; miners' demand for, 204-215 Industrial Crista cmd the Way Out, 239 Industrial Democracy, 91 "Industrial True*," 7 Industrial Unionists, and con- INDEX 275 tagious control, 264; Marx- ian, 5; shop stewards, 9 Industry, workers' control of, 15-18; joint control of, 224- 240 Interests in industry, worker's, 19-50; what he gets, 20-25; what it's for, 25-27 ; how he's treated, 27-38; what he does, 38-50 Inventions, 218-219 Irritation strike, 179 Joint action, see under Trade policy Joint control and price fixing, 169-171 Joint discipline, 147-150 Joint Industrial Council, for the Building Industry, 88, 113, 224, 227-228, 230; for the Silk Industry, 227-228 Juvenile Employment Commit- tee, 97 Labor Party, 157 Labor Unions, attitude toward innovations, 186-191; see also under Trade Unions and sep- arate titles Liverpool Docks Scheme, First Year's Working of, 79 Lloyd George, David, 60, 193 London Society of Compositors, 67; report of, 97 Machine industry, 39; produc- tion, 102 Managerial functions, 146-160; allocation of work, 155-156; measurement of results, 156- 159; safety of workers, 150, 154; wartime regulations, 147-149 Mann, Tom, 16, 76 Man Potcer Of the Nation, the, 29-30 Marxian Industrial Unionists, 6 Measurement of results, quan- tity, 157; quality, 158-159 Mining Association of Great Britain, scheme of, 250-251 Miners' Federation, of Great Britain, 1, 12-13, 42, 151-152, 154, 163-164, 192, 208, 209, 235, 244-245; of South Wales, 6, 152-156, 212-214, 235-236 " Miners' Four Days " policy, 254 Miners' Minimum Wage Act, 137, 167 Miners' Next Step, 105, 123, 144, 183, 263 Miners, complaints of, 205-206; improvements demanded by, 204-215 Miners' Nationalization Bill, 12-13 Ministry of Labor's Report on Works Committees, 40, 85, 108, 122, 140-141 Muir, John, 193 Munitions of War Act, 147-150 Murphy, J. T., 100, 102, 182, 265 National Guilds League, 6 National Industrial Conference, 132 Nationalization and Joint Con- trol, 26; miners' bill for, 6, 12, 13 National Union of Railway- men, 2-6, 4-5; policy of, 13- 14, 42, 61, 78 Northumberland miners, 49, 50 Officialism, revolt against, 8 Oldham agreement, 224-225 Output Committees, 149 Output, 210; restriction of, 177-185 Overtime, Union restrictions against, 74-75 Payment, and control, 164-165; collective, 163, 170-173; by results, 165; Bradford's Dyers' Association's system, 172-173; for work in abnor- mal places. 167; methods of, 161-176; South Wales Col- 276 INDEX liery Agreement for, 167; Woolen Trades' plan for, 167 Personal freedom, 34 Piece work, 162-163, 205; Bradford Dyers' Associa- tion's system of, 172-173; Phoenix Dynamo Company's objections to, 170; Wood- working Trades opposed to, 162 Phoenix Dynamo Co., 170-171 Pitfalls of the Promoted, the, 29 30 " Policing," 31, 137, 261 "Politics of industry," 176 Poor Law Commission Eeport, 86 Postal and Telegraph Clerks, 15, 112 Post Office Workers, 46 Power Loom Overlookers, 95 Premium bonus, 162-163 Production, regulation of, 243- 245 Promotion, 111-116; Federation of Weavers' rules for, 114; Joint Industrial Council's rules for, 112-113; Seniority rule for, 112; the workers' prerogative, 115 Publicity of profits, 249-251 "Rank and File Movement," 8 Rate fixing, 168-171 Redmayne, Sir Richard, testi- mony of, 205-206 Renold's, Hans, 120-121 Restriction and restrictions, 176-185 Richardson, Alexander, 131 Rowntree's, 121 "Sack," the right to, 102 et seq. Safety, 150-154; strikes, 152- 154 Sankey, Justice, quoted, 46 Sankey Report, 13, 222 Schloss, D. F., 36, 110, 125, 161- 162, 218 Scottish Master Tailors' state- ment, 73-74 Sharing of work, 73-74 Sheffield Workers* Committee, 9 Shop Committees and their du- ties, 200-201 Shop Stewards' Manual, 8-9, 140; movement, 7, 9-11, 255 Short time, 73-77 Sliding Scale, 243 Smillie, Robert, 154, 206, 215 Smith, Herbert, 24, 206 Socialism, fcitate, 25-27 Socialist Labor Party, 5 Sparkes, Malcolm, 227, 256 Specialization, 182, 183 Stay-in strike, 178-179 Steel Dressers' Agreement, 61 Stockholm International Labor Conference, 25 Straker, William, quoted, 3, 22, 27, 38, 221 ; testimony before Coal Commission, 33, 47 Strikes, against objectionable promotions, 114; against ob- jectionable supervision, 135- 137; against use of machin- ery, 184; because of a woman shop steward, 184; for rein- statement of operatives, 106- 107, 109; for safety, 152; Glasgow Dockers', 128; Iron Founders', 204 Stuff Pressers' Society, 69, 94, 117, 172, 263, 265 " Suggestion Boxes," 218 Suggestions, right to make, 43- 46 Syndicalism, 4 Tawney, R. H., 135, 258 Technique, consultation over changes, 186-201 ; insistence on improvements, 202-216; restriction and restrictions, 176-185; suggestions and in- ventions, 217-222 Thomas, J. H., 60 Thompson, William, 72 Trade Policy, joint action re- garding, 223-240; Joint In- INDEX 277 dustrial Councils, 226-227 ; Oldham Agreement, 224-225; publicity of profits, 249-251 ; scheme of Postal Telegraph Clerks' Association, 223-240; workers' demands, 241-252 Trade, the right to a, 92-103 Trades Union Congress, Glas- gow, 1919, 15-16, 18 Trade Union movement, 36 Trade Unions, and overtime, 14- 75; and short time, 75-77; as employment agencies, 66; at- titude toward promotions, 111; guaranteed time, 78-79; • membership of, 92-93; policy regarding foremen, 126-129, 142 Treasury Agreement, the, 171, 194-197 "Tuppenny Strike," 8 Turner, Ben, 47-48 Unemployment, 72 et seq.; a charge on the industry, 86 a matter of trade policy, 223 fear of restricts output, 87 prevention of, 86-91; schemes for lessening, 80-86; security against, 23 Unionized industry, 64-66 Unions as employment agencies, 66-70 Victimization, 104, 107-108 Wages, 20; and hours, 20-23, 53; collective contract, 173- 174; collective payment, 171- 173; methods of payment, 161 et acq.; piece work, 162- 173 " Wage Slavery," 38 Weavers' Manifesto, 242 Webb, Sidney and Beatrice, 36, 86, 91, 93, 112, 157, 203 Wedgwood's, 43 Whitehead Torpedo Works, 147 Whitley Councils, 5-6, 154, 226, 240; report of, 113-114, 192, 221, 248 Williams, R., 79 Woods, Frank, 97-98 Wool Control Board, 237, 249 Women labor, 102 Work, equalization of, 73-74 Workers, grievances of, 140- 142; interests in industry, 19-20, 38; methods of pay- ment of, 161 et seq.; objec- tion to being watched, 137- 138; resentment of, 29-35; safety of, 150-154; sensitive- ness of, 32; servility of, 33; treatment of, 27-29 Workers' Control, see under Control Working Shedulcs, 156 Workmanship, 46-49; collective, 43 Works' Council, 231-233 Yorkshire Glass Bottle Work- ers, 74 4UD SfeSO THE LIBRARY UNIVERSITY OF CALIFORNIA Santa Barbara THIS BOOK IS DUE ON THE LAST DATE STAMPED BELOW. UC SOUTHERN REGIONAL LIBRARY FACILITY A 000 716 428 8